CHAPTER 27
It has been understood for a long time by bankers and
politicians that confidence plays an important role in finance. Economists, in
contrast, have been slow to realize this. As a result a strong tradition in the
economics literature that discusses what confidence is and what role it plays
does not exist. The main theoretical as well as empirical work in this area, in
short, remains to be done. The same is also true for establishing what economists
so far have said about the role of confidence in finance. Again, the result is
a weak, close to nonexistent, understanding of what confidence is.
One may speculate why this is the case. One
factor may be that mainstream economics focuses on a narrow set of factors
that drive economic behavior, and confidence is not one of them. It is, for
example, possible to argue that one can make good analyses without taking
confidence into account. This is an argument that needs to be taken seriously,
and those who advocate that there is a need for a better understanding of confidence
in finance must be prepared to show how this will improve the analysis.
Another reason for the neglect of confidence
in the analysis of finance has to do with the common conviction among
economists that confidence belongs to the field of psychology, not economics.
To this can be added the fact that mainstream economics has by tradition not
been very interested in psychology, including the field of economic psychology
that was created by George Katona and others in the 1950s (e.g., Katona 1975).
A more successful attempt to bring psychology and economics together can be
found in behavioral economics, a topic to which I shall return later in this
chapter.
Sociology has for natural reasons had even
less to say about the role of confidence in finance. Economic sociology has
only been around for a few decades and has not produced very many studies of
finance. This is true even if we take into account the work by sociologists who
are active in the field known as the social studies of finance (but see, e.g.,
Knorr Cetina and Preda 2005; Pixley 2004).
Given the absence in economics as well as in
sociology of a well-developed tradition that studies the role of confidence in
finance, I will structure this chapter as follows.
530 RICHARD SWEDBERG
I will first introduce the main attempts so far to deal
with this topic, in economics as well as in sociology. The reasons for
discussing the contribution by economists in a handbook of sociology are two.
First, the economists have had much more to say about confidence in finance
than sociologists have. Second, and following Schumpeter’s dictum that economic
sociology consists of an area that is situated at the intersection of sociology
and economics, it is natural for the study of confidence in finance to draw on
both of these sciences (Schumpeter 1954: 25-7).
Since so little work on this topic exists—and so little
consensus on the role of confidence in finance—it is also necessary to touch
on a few related topics in this chapter. One of these has to do with the
relationship between trust and confidence. According to the everyday use of
these two terms, for example, they have related and partly overlapping
meanings—but is this also the case for the way they are used in economics and
sociology? It is clear as well that the role of confidence is not limited to
the area of the economy, and, in the economy, to the area of finance. What
lessons can be learned from general discussions of confidence as well as from
discussions of confidence in economic life in general? Addressing topics and
questions of this type increases the difficulties in dealing with the topic of
confidence in finance and takes it in divergent directions.
In order to give the reader a sense of how economists
have looked at confidence, I will start out by presenting the content of one of
the few overviews of this topic that exist (and perhaps even the only one). It
is a brief article entitled “Confidence," which appeared in The New Palgrave Dictionary
of Money and Finance (Walters 1992). It appeared in the early 1990s and is
written by Alan Walters, a British expert on money and finance.
Walters makes two major points in his
article. The first is that confidence plays a very small role in modern
economics: “Confidence . . . is largely ignored by modern theoretical
economics” (Walters 1992: 423). The second is that confidence is primarily a
psychological phenomenon—and it is this fact that makes it so hard to for
economists to deal with confidence. “Economists’ tools and models” Walters
says, show a distinct “inability” to analyze confidence, without resorting to
“market psychology” (Walters 1992:
424-5).
But even if a basic incompatibility between
economic theory and the psychological phenomenon of confidence exists,
economists have for a long time nonetheless discussed various forms of
confidence. According to Walters, their interest has taken three forms: they
have developed surveys of confidence; they have looked at the role of confidence
in the business cycle; and they have studied confidence and governmental
policy.
Surveys of confidence include the famous
surveys of consumer confidence that have been produced since the 1960s by the
Conference Board and the Survey Research Center at the University of Michigan.
But to Walters these surveys do not really address the issue of confidence, but
what people think that the economy will be like in the future. He concludes:
“it is doubtful if these surveys of confidence help in understanding the
effects that confidence has on economic conditions” (Walters 1992: 423).
Walters’ discussion of surveys of confidence
is very brief, and it does not at any point address the issue of finance. His
attitude to what he calls “business confidence” and its role in the business
cycle is different. He devotes far more space to this topic, for one thing. He
also notes that this topic includes finance, in the form of “financial panics”
Walters centers his discussion of the role
of confidence in the business cycle around a work that probably few people are
familiar with—The Trade Cycle (1922) by Frederick Lavington. According to Lavington,
businessmen make their decisions in a rational manner. At times, however, their
decisions are colored by hope; this results in “unduly high confidence or
optimism” (Walters 1992: 423). And sometimes their decisions are colored by
apprehension, which results in “unduly low confidence or pessimism” (Walters
1992: 423).
Lavington’s analysis makes us realize that
the notion of confidence is linked to optimism and pessimism, even if it may
be hard to pinpoint the exact difference between a strong sense of confidence
and optimism, on the one hand, and an absence of confidence and pessimism, on
the other. Walters, in presenting Lavington to the reader, also introduces a
few other concepts that are commonly found in discussions of confidence: uncertainty and animal spirits. If there is uncertainty, he
suggests, there will be room for the animal spirits. And, depending on the
strength of the animal spirits, there will be little or no confidence.
The concept of animal spirits comes from
Keynes, and Walters refers to the British economist several times in his
article. We are, for example, told that one can find a rudimentary form of
confidence multiplier already in Lavington, and that the idea of surveys of
confidence traces its origin to Keynes’ work. And Keynes argued that confidence
varies directly with the faith we have in our forecasts.
Walters also directs some criticism at
Keynes, especially for not working out the effects of confidence on the
business cycle. The reason for this omission, he says, is that Keynes felt that
confidence “was mainly a matter for business psychology rather than for
analytical economics” (Walters 1992: 424).
The third topic that Walters surveys in his
article is confidence and government policy. This type of confidence
essentially deals with the type of confidence that the general public as well
as businesspeople have in the way the government handles the economy. Walters suggests
that what is ultimately at issue here is consistency. In order to inspire
confidence, government policy in economic affairs has to be credible—and for it
to be credible, it has to be consistent.
An economic policy that is internally
inconsistent will fail, according to Walters. As an example he mentions a
situation in which the budget deficit is not properly aligned with the monetary
policy or with the inflation rate. Walters also attacks Keynes’ idea that the
government should counter downturns in the business cycle, with the argument
that this is very likely to erode confidence. The reason for this is that in
the end a deficit always has to be paid off.
While Walters’ article can serve as an introduction
to the role of confidence in economics, it also needs to be complemented. One
reason is that it is very short and fails to do justice to, say, the
contribution of Keynes. Another reason is that quite a bit has happened with
the analysis of confidence during the 20 years or so since Walters’ article was
written.
When did economists start looking at
confidence? Histories of economics typically begin with The Wealth of Nations (1776), and one may
therefore ask if its author had something to say on the topic. The answer is
that the closest Adam Smith comes to a discussion of confidence is in his
remarks on the role of a merchant’s reputation. According to Smith, there is
variation in the “character” displayed by merchants from different countries.
The Dutch are “more faithful to their word” and better at “performing agreements”
than say the English. And the English, in their turn, are more faithful and so
on than the Scots. Adam Smith also notes that the more frequently people
interact with one another, the more important it is for the actors to have
“character.” The reason for this, he suggests, has to do with “self-interest,”
which “leads men to act in a certain manner from views of advantage” (Smith
[1766] 1997: 17).
These remarks on reputation and character
are not to be found in The Wealth of Nations but in Lectures of Jurisprudence, something that again alerts
us to the fact that confidence is a topic that tends to lie outside the normal
domain of the economist. And again we find a new topic—this time, reputation—that is close to, and
overlaps with, confidence, without being identical to it. It should also be
noted that by linking interest so closely to confidence, Adam Smith can be seen
as an early proponent of the calcula- tive view of confidence.
While an expert on the history of
nineteenth-century economics might continue in this vein and point to some
minor statements on confidence in the works of Ricardo, Mill, and so on, I
shall limit myself to a discussion of a single work from this century. It is,
however, a work that has much to say about the role of confidence in finance: Lombard Street (1873) by Walter Bagehot.
Keynes has called this book “one of the
classics in Political Economy” (Keynes 1915: 369). The main reason for singling
it out for discussion in this chapter is that it is probably the most
influential work ever written on the role of confidence in finance. It is in
this work, more precisely, that the classical strategy for how a central bank
can restore confidence in a financial crisis was first outlined. During the
recent financial crisis, for example, Bernanke repeatedly referred to what
Bagehot says in Lombard Street (e.g., Bernanke 2008, 2009).
Bagehot’s purpose in writing Lombard Street was first and foremost to
make the financial community in England realize that the Bank of England,
which was a private bank at the time, must resume the kind of responsibilities
that we today associate with a central bank. England was at the time the banker
of the world; and the concentration of capital that could be found in the
financial district of London well surpassed that of any other
financial power. Banking was, however, also
very vulnerable to crises—and unless certain measures were taken, Bagehot
argued, one of them could destroy the English banks.
Confidence and trust (and Bagehot used the
two terms interchangeably) stand at the very center of his analysis of the
fragile nature of the banking system. “Credit means that a certain confidence
is given, and a certain trust reposed” he writes (Bagehot [1873] 1922: 22).
“‘Is the trust justified and is that confidence wise’? These are the cardinal
questions”
What Bagehot refers to in this quote is the
kind of confidence that a banker must have in the person to whom money is lent.
But this is only side of the equation. The other side has to do with the
confidence that the depositor has to have in the bank, in order to part with
the money. In France, for example, Bagehot notes, many people do not trust the
banks and therefore keep their money at home.
At both ends of the banking business, in
other words, confidence is crucial. Or in Bagehot’s words: “The peculiar
essence of our banking system is an unprecedented trust between man and man”
(Bagehot [1873] 1922: 151). This “unprecedented trust” also means that the
banker has to do anything he can to keep people calm and not to endanger
confidence. One classical line in Lombard Street reads: “Adventure is the life of commerce,
but caution, I had almost said timidity, is the life of banking” (Bagehot
[1873] 1922: 220-1). Another related quote reads: “Every banker knows that if
he has to prove
that he
is worthy of credit, however good may be his arguments, in fact his credit is
gone” (Bagehot [1873] 1922: 68).
Panics, however, or sudden losses of
confidence, do occur; and Bagehot devotes many pages to analyze how these can
be triggered, and what can be done to stop them and restore confidence. Losses
in the loan portfolio of banks are extra dangerous for precisely this reason.
And, especially in cases when the losses are hidden and suddenly disclosed,
the crisis can bring down the whole financial system.
The best way to stop a crisis and restore
confidence, Bagehot famously says, is to “lend freely” (e.g., Bagehot [1873] 1922: 48, 64;
emphasis added). When a panic is on, the natural instinct for a banker is to
hold tight to the money. In this situation, Bagehot argues, the central
bank—the Bank of England—must behave differently. It must lend freely and, by
giving the impression that it has confidence in the system, it will restore
confidence.
It was earlier mentioned that Keynes
regarded Lombard
Street as
a classic in economics. He especially praised Bagehot’s gift for observing
what was going on in real life. He had less appreciation, however, for
Bagehot’s analytical skills and basically felt that Bagehot was more of a
psychologist than an economist. “Lombard Street” Keynes sums up, “is the Psychology of
Finance, not the theory of it” (Keynes 1915: 373). This is another instance, in
short, of the view that confidence is important in real life—but that economics
unfortunately cannot deal with it.
Next to Bagehot, Keynes is the economist who
has made the most important contribution to the analysis of confidence. While
Bagehot concentrated on the role of confidence in the banking system and how
to handle its sudden disappearance in a crisis, Keynes was more interested in
the role that confidence plays in the regular working of the economy and
especially how it influenced investments. Keynes touches on confidence in many
of his writings, but most importantly in General Theory (Keynes 1936; see also Keynes 1937).
The main question that Keynes raises in General Theory is how full employment and
steady economic growth can be ensured in a society with a capitalist economy.
His well- known answer is that the state has to intervene in order to increase
demand and to steer investments in a productive direction. This is also the
general picture into which Keynes fits confidence. The role of confidence, he
argues, is crucial; and that is to help offset the uncertainty that is
inevitably part the decision to make an investment. Investments cannot
exclusively be made based on rational considerations; they also involve
confidence.
Keynes’ analysis of confidence can be found
in the famous chapter 12 in General Theory, which contains his most important
contribution to the sociological analysis of the economy (Keynes 1936: 147-64).
Besides its analysis of confidence, this remarkable chapter (which deserves to
be known as a classic in economic sociology) also introduces such well-known
Keynesian notions as animal spirits and the stock market as a beauty contest.
These two latter concepts are usually presented and discussed in their own right,
but as we soon shall see they are closely linked to the phenomenon of
confidence.
Keynes starts out from the idea that
investment represents the key to production and economic growth. Investments,
however, also depend on an evaluation of distant events and these are
impossible to know. On this point Keynes refers to his own work on statistics
and argues that probabilities simply do not apply to future events. Rational
calculations cannot present a solution; the only way you can proceed is with
the help of confidence. Confidence, from this perspective, is defined as “how
highly we rate the likelihood of our best forecast to be wrong” (Keynes 1936:
148).
At this point of the argument in chapter 12 Keynes
stops and presents the reader with the fullest statement that can be found in
his work on the role of confidence in economic life:
The state of confidence, as they term it, is a matter
to which practical men always pay the closest and most anxious attention. But
economists have not analyzed it carefully and have been content, as a rule, to
discuss it in general terms. In particular it has not been made clear that its
relevance to economic problems comes in through its important influence on the
schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital. There are not two separate
factors affecting the rate of investment, namely the schedule of the marginal
efficiency of capital and the state of confidence. The state of confidence is
relevant because it is one of the major factors determining the former, which
is the same thing as the investment demand-schedule.
There is,
however, not much to be said about the state of confidence a priori. Our conclusions must mainly
depend upon the actual observation of markets and business psychology. This is
the reason why the ensuing digression is on a different level of abstraction
from most of this book. (Keynes 1936: 148-9)
Note that so far Keynes has argued that confidence is
indispensable to the key problem of economics, namely production and economic
growth. He has also stated that econo-
THE ROLE OF CONFIDENCE IN FINANCE 535
mists have ignored confidence and that it must be
introduced into economic theory. But how does Keynes want to proceed from this
point onward? His answer, to repeat, is as follows: “Our conclusions must
mainly depend upon the actual observation of markets and business psychology.
This is the reason why the ensuing digression is on a different level of
abstraction from most of this book.”
Keynes, in other words, says that he will
rely on precisely the two qualities that made it possible for Bagehot to deal
with confidence: observation and psychology. But even if he attempted to go beyond
Bagehot and introduce confidence into economic theory, he also says that he
will be unable to proceed in the same way as he does elsewhere in General Theory.
Keynes’ answer to the question of how
confidence helps actors to handle faraway events or to form long-term
expectations is as follows. In the stock market actors not only make forecasts
as best as they can, they also depend on “conventions,” and this provides them
with the confidence they need for their forecasts. In starting up and in running
firms, businessmen have to make forecasts. And what gives them confidence is
something else: animal spirits.
On the stock market the private investor
draws on a convention for how to evaluate the stocks; to the extent that this
is done, he or she is able to proceed with confidence. This type of confidence,
however, is brittle in nature, since these conventions are based on superficial
knowledge and are easily influenced by what other actors think. Since
confidence on the stock market is structured in this particular way, it is
inherently unstable.
Adding to the problem, from Keynes’
perspective, is that professional investors do not have long-term productivity
as their goal. What they try to do is essentially to figure out how the private
investors view the market. This is where Keynes’ famous theory of the stock market
as a beauty contest comes into the picture. Professional investors try “to
anticipate what average opinion expects the average opinion to be” (Keynes
1936: 156). What happens on the stock market, according to Keynes, consequently
depends on “the state of confidence of the speculator,” and the problem is that
this type of confidence is based on conventions that have little to do with
production (Keynes 1936: 158).
Keynes also discusses the confidence of
another key actor in the modern economy, namely the businessman; this type of
confidence differs in many ways from that of the speculator on the stock
market. Instead of being based on inherently unstable conventions, it draws on
animal spirits or the spontaneous urge that human beings have to act. These
types of emotions particularly dominated economic life before the separation of
ownership and management of the firm, according to Keynes, but are still
operative in the modern economy.
The tendency is nonetheless for the
activities on the stock market (“speculation”) to be more important for the
economy than those of individual businessmen (“enterprise”). This means that
investments will be handled in a poor way and that the state has to intervene
and assume some responsibility for investments. What consequences this will
have for confidence, Keynes does not say. It would seem to entail a third type
of confidence, however, namely confidence in the state as an economic actor.
After Keynes very little attention was paid
to confidence in the economics literature till the 1970s. From this time onward
modern economics has become more pluralistic, and it has opened up to many new
types of analyses such as game theory, behavioral economics, neuroeconomics,
and so on. In several of these new approaches one can find studies that deal
with confidence. It is hard to generalize, but there seems to be a tendency to
either use the term “confidence” and cast it as a psychological and nonra-
tional phenomenon, or to use the term “trust” and see it in more structural and
rational terms.
Behavioral economics draws on psychology to
recast economic analysis and tends to use the term confidence. The most
important stream of research in this type of approach is centered around the
idea of overconfidence and has its origin in a
pioneering study from 1992 by Dale Griffin and Amos Tversky (see also Pech and
Milan 2009). Overconfidence is here interpreted to mean that “people are more
confident in their judgments than is warranted by the facts” (Griffin and Tversky
1992: 411). The article by Griffin and Tversky mainly uses examples that have
nothing to do with finance, but the authors also note that overconfidence can
lead to “regrettable financial investments” (Griffin and Tversky 1992: 432).
Today’s behavioral economics is very broad
in scope and also has a macroeconomic branch, as exemplified most importantly
by the work of Robert Shiller. Among Shiller’s many attempts to take confidence
into account, there is, for example, his work on investor confidence, including
his Index of Investor Confidence (e.g., Shiller 1999, 2000: 44-68). His most
important attempt to outline a theory of confidence for macroeconomic analysis
is, however, to be found in a recent book coauthored with George Akerlof, Animal Spirits.
In this study, the authors state that while
most of economic life can be understood with the help of the concept of
interest, along the lines first outlined by Adam Smith, there is also another
part of economics that can only be explained by referring to man’s “noneconomic
motivations” or animal spirits (Akerlof and Shiller 2009: 3). These animal
spirits account in particular for two very important aspects of economic life:
its variation and its sharp fluctuations.
While animal spirits is a term that comes from
Keynes, Akerlof and Shiller have reinterpreted it for their own purposes. It no
longer means man’s spontaneous urge to action, but instead covers the following
five phenomena: confidence, temptations, envy, resentment, and illusions.
Akerlof and Shiller state that confidence
represents “the corner stone of our theory” and that it should be used in a way
that differs from that in which most economists currently use it (Akerlof and
Shiller 2009: 5). When economists have discussed confidence, they have mainly
seen it in terms of a multiple equilibria analysis and/or as a bleak attitude
to the future. The argument has been that without confidence, you may get stuck
in an undesirable equilibrium; and with the help of confidence, you can move to
a better economic future.
To Akerlof and Shiller this view of
confidence is wrong since it “suggests that confidence is rational,” while
“the very meaning of trust is that we go beyond the rational”
(Akerlof and Shiller 2009: 12). As an example
of how confidence (or rather its disappearance) can affect finance, they
mention the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008.
The main suggestion of Akerlof and Shiller
on how to introduce confidence into economic theory has to do with something
they call the “confidence multiplier.” Drawing on Keynes’ idea of the
multiplier, they suggest that a confidence multiplier indicates “the change in
income that results from a one-unit change in confidence—however it might be
conceived or measured” (Akerlof and Shiller 2009: 16).
If we now turn to the approaches in modern economics
that prefer to use the term trust, and not confidence, we find that the
emphasis is more on stability, rationality, and the broadly social qualities of
trust, than on irrationality and individual psychology. The tone of this line
of research can be illustrated by a famous statement on the role of trust by
Kenneth Arrow. In The Limits of Organization, he describes trust as “an
important lubricant of a social system” (Arrow 1974: 23; cf. Arrow 2009). The
full quote reads as follows:
Now trust has a very
important pragmatic value, if nothing else. Trust is an important lubricant of
a social system. It is extremely efficient; it saves a lot of trouble to have a
fair reliance on other people’s word. (Arrow 1974: 23)
From the characterization of trust as something
efficient and stable, there is only a small step to what Oliver Williamson has
called “calculative trust” (Williamson 1993: 463-4). This approach is also
often used in game theoretical analyses of trust. It similarly informs the
increasing number of empirical studies of trusts that have been carried out by
economists. Rafael La Porta and his coauthors show, for example, that there
exists a relationship between the number of trusting people in a country and
its level of inflation and GDP growth rate (La Porta et al. 1997).
Neuroeconomists also seem to identify more
with the view that is implicit in the concept of trust, than with the focus on
uncertainty that can be found in the research on confidence (e.g., Fehr 2008).
The main insight in neuroeconomics is that trust is linked to a hormone called
oxytocin, which is related to the tendency of human beings to be social.
Oxytocin has its origin in the brain and affects the organs through the bloodstream.
In one of his experiments Ernst Fehr administered oxytocin to a number of students
through a nasal spray and then told them to play a so-called trust game, which
involved investing a sum of money. Students who received a dose of oxytocin
were more willing to trust their financial partners than those who did not
receive the hormone (Angier 2009).
While economists who do work in finance have
not shown much interest in trust, there does exist today a small body of work
in this highly technical field (Sapienza 2009). What view of trust one can find
in this type of economics can be gleaned from an article that was published in
2008 in the Journal of Finance, “Trust in the Stock Market” (Guiso, Sapienza, and
Zingales 2008). Its key argument is that trust can help to explain the puzzle
of why so few people invest in stocks. The more trust there is in a country,
the more its citizens will invest in the stock market.
The authors define trust as “the subjective
probability individuals attribute to the possibility of being cheated” (Guiso,
Sapienza, and Zingales 2008: 2557). There exist “outer factors” that influence
individuals to buy stocks (such as the quality of investor protection) as well
as “interior factors” (such as their education and religion). The authors also
refer to cross-country data. The conclusion of the study is that less trusting
individuals are less likely to buy stocks—and if they do buy stocks, they buy
less.
I earlier referred to Schumpeter’s statement that economic
sociology is situated somewhere in the gray area between economics and
sociology, and the sociological flavor of the study of trust and participation
in the stock market is incontestable. This is also true for much of the other
research on confidence and trust that has been discussed. Bagehot’s ideas on
why confidence is especially important in the banking business are, for example,
easily cast in sociological terms. And even if Keynes always referred to
psychology and never to sociology when he discussed confidence, there is a
clear sociological dimension to his analysis.
While economists to some extent have theorized both the
concept of trust and that of confidence, this is not the case with sociologists.
Why sociologists have looked at trust but not at confidence is not clear. One
clue, however, can be found in the one and only major sociological study
devoted to the phenomenon of confidence, namely Rosabeth Moss Kanter’s (2006) Confidence. What Kanter means by
confidence, it turns out, is a belief in oneself. Confidence, in other words,
has probably been viewed by sociologists as a psychological phenomenon, just as
in economics. And since Durkheim, sociologists have tended to stay away from
truly psychological phenomena and mainly focus on what takes place outside the
individual, as opposed to what happens inside the mind of the individual actor.
But if sociologists do not use confidence as
a distinct concept in its own right, this does not mean that they have a
unitary concept of trust. As it turns out, modern sociologists have produced a
bewildering number of theories of trust. Before addressing this issue and
discussing what it entails for the analysis of confidence in finance, however,
it is useful to look at some earlier contributions by sociologists to the
understanding of trust.
Of the classics, it is especially Simmel and
Weber who have written on trust. Weber did not develop a special concept of
trust but used a variety of related and overlapping terms. His most successful
analysis of trust is probably to be found in his analysis of political
legitimation. Coercion is not enough to dominate a population in the long run,
Weber argued; something else is needed to inspire trust in the ruler. The three
types of legitimation were his answer.
Weber also made some interesting
contributions to the understanding of trust in economic life. One of these can
be found in “The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism” in which he
notes that people in the United States tended to trust individuals who were
members of certain religious sects (Weber [1920] 1946). During his trip to the
United States, Weber also says in this article, he ran into a person who wanted
to become a banker and who therefore became a Baptist. He knew, Weber says,
that if he joined a sect, people would have no difficulty in trusting him with
their money (Weber [1920] 1946: 304-5).
It can also be argued that Weber’s concept
of rational capitalism has an important component of trust. What makes rational
capitalism so superior to other forms of capitalism, according to Weber, is
precisely its predictable nature. Merchants and other economic actors can
trust that courts, the state and so on will act in a certain manner. Without this
predictability or trust, Weber notes, it would not be possible to mobilize the
huge sums of capital that are necessary in the modern economy.
Simmel discusses trust in Philosophy of Money as well as in his general
sociology (Simmel [1907] 1978: 178-9, 480; 1950: 318-20, 345-8). In the former
work he cites the inscription of a Corsican coin: non aes sedfides (“Not money, but trust”).
Trust, Simmel explains, is crucial to the existence of money in two ways.
First, you have to trust that a certain coin is worth a certain amount. And
second, you have to trust that other people will accept the coin at its value.
Simmel discusses money and trust in Philosophy of Money, but he also touches on
credit and trust. What he has in mind with credit, however, is personal credit
and not the kind of credit on which the banking system is based. In general, it
seems that Simmel knew very little about banking and the stock market.
Simmel was, however, very interested in
trust as a general phenomenon, in society as well as in the economy, and also
in different types of trust. On the one hand, he suggested, there exists a
kind of trust that is based primarily on knowledge. If you know something
completely, Simmel says, you do not need to trust. But if you do trust, there
is always a chance that you may be wrong; “any trust always entails a risk”
(Simmel [1907] 1978: 480). A farmer, for example, typically trusts that there
will be a harvest next year, and he bases this on empirical grounds.
Translators of Simmel’s work into English
often render the word Vertrauen in this type of context as “confidence” But
Simmel also used this term for another type of trust; here the translators use
“trust.” In the latter case there is something else involved besides knowledge.
This something else, Simmel said, is “hard to define” but has its clearest
expression in religious faith (Simmel [1907] 1978: 178). His most precise
attempt to define this element can be found in his description of it as an
“element of social-psychological quasi-religious faith” (Simmel [1907] 1978:
179). Simmel was clearly looking for a word to describe trust that had some
elements in common with religious faith, but which also differed from it.
Perhaps secular faith is close to what he had in mind with “quasireligious
faith”
Before leaving Simmel, it is important to
note that he emphasizes the interactional dimension of trust and confidence
more than its psychological and individual dimension. Trust and confidence, he
says, are something that “people have in each other” (Simmel [1907] 1978: 178).
But the interaction involved is not the same for these two concepts. While
confidence tends to be something you give, trust is something you tend to
accept (Simmel 1950: 348).
Just as the economists reacted to, and
received important inspiration from, the events of the Great Depression in the
1930s, so did the sociologists. One particular analysis of the events during
this period has become a sociological classic. This is Robert K. Merton’s
analysis of a run on a bank in his essay “The Self-Fulfilling Prophecy” (Merton
[1948] 1968).
Merton mentions that in the early 1920s some
600 banks went silently bankrupt every year in the United States, and that this
figure nearly quadrupled during the years before and after the crash of 1929.
The way that even a good bank could go bankrupt during these years inspired
Merton to an ideal-typical account of what happens during a run on a bank. He
cast his analysis as a story about the fictional Last National Bank, set in the
year of 1932. A rumor that this perfectly healthy bank was insolvent made
depositors withdraw their money—and this pushed the bank into bankruptcy.
Merton explains what happened in the following way:
The stable financial
structure of the bank had depended upon one set of definitions of the
situation: belief in the validity of the interlocking system of economic promises
men live by. Once depositors had defined the situation otherwise, once they
questioned the possibility of having these promises fulfilled, the consequences
of this unreal definition were real enough. (Merton [1948] 1968: 476)
While Merton speaks of changes in “beliefs” and “the
fulfillment of promises” as the key mechanism involved, it is clear that these
terms are very close to confidence or trust. And what Merton describes in terms
of the Thomas theorem and a self-fulfilling prophecy can equally well be
presented as a classical run on a bank caused by its depositors losing
confidence. Merton also points out that this type of run on banks can be
blocked through “enacted institutional change” (Merton [1948] 1968: 489). As we
know, this came about through the creation of the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation in 1933.
Since the 1980s two developments have
occurred that are of importance to the discussion of how sociologists view the
role of confidence in finance. One of these is the reemergence of economic
sociology and the related social studies of finance. The other is the huge
amount of attention that has been devoted to the concept of trust. The latter
development has involved not only sociologists but social scientists in
general.
As earlier mentioned, contemporary economic
sociologists have had little to say about confidence and trust. While it is
often pointed out that credit implies trust and that the term credit comes from
the Latin credere, which means to trust, this
is usually also where the analysis stops. One major exception to this tendency
does, however, exist, and this is the attempt to portray trust (and confidence)
as an emotion.
The two proponents of this view are Jocelyn
Pixley and Jack Barbalet, both of whom are influenced by Keynes’ ideas about
uncertainty and animal spirits. Barbalet is a pioneer in the sociology of
emotions (as well as active in economic sociology); his work is primarily
relevant in this context for the interest that he has shown in the concept of
confidence (Barbalet 1998: 82-102; for a critique of Barbalet, see Dequech
2001). According to Barbalet, confidence as an emotion consists of two
elements, one that is cognitive and another that is dispositional in nature.
“The cognitive element of confidence involves images of projections of self
and beliefs concerning the future. The dispositional aspect concerns inclinations
to act on those images, projections, and beliefs” (Barbalet 1998: 85).
Jocelyn Pixley’s main contribution can be
found in her monograph Emotions in Finance (2004), which is based on interviews with
some 40 people in finance, from central bankers to finance journalists. Her
main thesis, inspired by Keynes, is that the future is unknowable and that the
only way to proceed is to go beyond rational calculations.
Pixley argues that trust, confidence,
credibility, and similar phenomena are all emotions that must complement
rational calculations in order for forecasts or actions directed toward the
future to be possible. The type of emotions involved, she says (and here she
leaves Keynes), are social in nature and often carefully managed by central
banks, private banks, and some other actors. The main problem, from Pixley’s
perspective, is that the modern financial system is based on making short-term
profits, and this means that the type of trust it produces is volatile in
nature. The tendency in finance is also to deny the very existence of emotions
and only to speak in terms of risk, something that adds to this volatility. The
solution to the instability of modern finance, the author suggests, is caution
and democracy.
Pixley primarily talks in terms of trust; it
is now time to take a brief look at the social science discussion of this
concept that was begun in the 1980s and has become very vigorous. The first
and perhaps also the most important fact about this discussion is that it has
led to no consensus whatsoever about what is meant by trust (see, e.g., Hardin
2001). Some scholars focus on its rational element, while others cast trust in
terms of probability. There also exist a number of studies that portray trust
as a very broad phenomenon that is closely related to the notion of social
capital. One example of this is Trust by Francis Fukuyama, in which economic prosperity is
closely linked to what the author defines as trust (“the expectation that
arises within a community of regular, honest, and cooperative behavior, based
on commonly shared norms, on the part of other members of that community”
(Fukuyama 1995: 26)).
In most of the literature on trust, no
particular attention is paid to the concept of confidence and the two terms
are used interchangeably. There do exist a few exceptions, however, and one of
these evokes the ideas of Simmel on trust as quasi-religious faith (see also,
e.g., Luhman 1988: 97, Seligman 1997: 25-6). This is in an essay by economic
anthropologist Keith Hart (1988), which can be found in the influential
anthology on trust edited by Diego Gambetta. Drawing on evidence in
dictionaries, he points to the link that exists between religious faith and
trust. “Faith,” he writes, “is an
emotionally charged unquestioning acceptance” (Hart 1988: 187). “Trust implies depth and assurance
of such feeling, with inconclusive evidence or proof. Confidence involves less intensity of
feeling, being based often on good evidence for being sure.”
Similar to Simmel, Hart views confidence as being more
or less the same as trust, minus most of the quasi-religious element. Hart
rejects the idea of a simple continuum, from faith over trust to confidence.
While some kind of continuum is involved, the concept of trust contains
elements of faith as well as evidence. Hart does not say if this is also true
for confidence, but possibly this is the case even if the element of faith
would be less than in trust.
So far in this chapter I have presented and commented
on contributions by economists and sociologists that in one way or another deal
with confidence in general and confidence in finance. It is clear that there
exists no consensus either in economics or in sociology when it comes to what
confidence is and what role it plays in finance.
My own impression is also that such a
consensus is not likely to emerge. And since this is the case for trust, it is
even more so for confidence. What needs to be done is therefore to try to push
ahead theoretically, to advance beyond the current discussion by putting forth
new ideas on this topic.
This is what I have attempted to do in an
analysis of the role of confidence in the current financial crises (Swedberg
2010). I here suggest that confidence has a double structure, in the sense
that we typically have confidence in something because there is something else
we want to know but cannot know. We do not have full knowledge of this
something else and therefore have to rely on some kind of substitute, in which
we place our confidence. I may, for example, have confidence that some bank
will respond in some manner, because it has done so several times before. I may
also have confidence in how a rating agency evaluates a bond issue, because I
know that this agency has a good reputation.
Confidence, and here I think that Barbalet
and Hart are correct, does not only have a cognitive dimension but also an
emotional and more holistic one, involving the whole person and not just his or
her calculative capacity (what Simmel attempts to capture through his
expression “quasi-religious faith”). The reason for this has not only to do
with the fact, I would argue, that one draws on confidence in situations where
one lacks full knowledge; there also exists another and more important reason.
This is that confidence is only fully manifested when some action is based on
it, since this forces the actor to go beyond whatever knowledge he or she has
and, so to speak, take a jump into the unknown.
Trust, I agree with Simmel and Hart, belongs
to the same family of phenomena as confidence, but its element of
quasi-religious faith is stronger. Confidence, I would argue, is more common in
the area of the modern economy, where actors have to be very alert, than in such
areas of life as religion, politics, and family. In these latter areas, faith
and loyalty are common as well as important.
A solid theory of confidence must also be
capable of handling different types of actors. In discussions of confidence and
trust, the actor is typically assumed to be an individual. The reason for this
is probably that trust and confidence are seen as psychological in nature, and
psychology deals with the individual. In the modern economy, however, the main
actors are institutions; trust and confidence have consequently to be theorized
in such a way that they cover institutions as well as individuals.
What existing theories of trust and
confidence do not take into account, I also would argue, is the existence of signs and their role more
generally in society (for signaling and trust, see Bacharach and Gambetta
2001). In both trust and confidence, to repeat, you have to rely on something
else than full knowledge; this something else, I suggest, can be conceptualized
as a sign.
The actor has to find a sign that he or she
can rely on, which indicates that something really exists or will happen. If
friends vouch for someone being honest, this is a sign; if some person
repeatedly has proven reliable, that is another sign. One may call this type of
sign a proxy
sign,
since it stands in for something else that we want to know but lack full
knowledge of. In my own work on the economy, I draw especially on the work of
American philosopher Charles Peirce, for the understanding of what a sign is
and how it operates (e.g., Peirce 1991; Swedberg 2011). Signs, according to
Peirce, include words but cover a much wider range.
By introducing an intermediary layer of
signs into the analysis between the actor and whatever he or she has confidence
in, one also increases that layer’s accessibility to sociological analysis.
There are actors who create signs as well as actors who interpret them, and
both of these processes can easily be analyzed sociologically. There also exist
different kinds of signs, all of which have a history that can be illuminated
with the help of sociology.
The idea of signs may open up the analysis
of confidence in finance to new conceptualizations. In Merton’s run on the
bank, for example, depositors read signs (rumors) and act on these. And,
according to Bagehot, bankers have to be extra vigilant in managing signs
because of the peculiar role that confidence plays in deposit banking. Or, to
take a recent example from the financial crisis, the rating agencies were much
too lax in assigning evaluations to stocks and bonds, and the same was true
for the investors who relied on these evaluations.
It would probably take another chapter to properly
outline what role signs play in the different types of confidence that are part
of finance. There is investor confidence, confidence in the banks, confidence
in the state, and so on. Still, by introducing the concept of signs into the
analysis, it is my belief that it can be substantially improved—and also that
it can start moving in new and exciting directions.
Akerlof, G.
and Shiller, R. (2009). Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the
Economy, and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press. Angier, N. (2009). “The Biology Behind the Milk of Human
Kindness.” The
New York Times, November 24: D2.
Arrow, K.
(1974). The
Limits of Organization. New York: W.W. Norton.
------ (2009).
“The Economy of Trust” (interview). Acton Institute. <http://www.acton.org/
publications/randl/rl_interview_556.php>
(accessed January 22, 2010).
Bacharach, M.
and Gambetta, D. (2001). “Trust in Signs,” in Karen Cook (ed.), Trust in Society. New York: Russell Sage
Foundation, 148-84.
Bagehot, W. ([1873] 1922). Lombard Street:
A Description of the Money Market. London: John Murray.
Barbalet, J.
(1998). Emotions,
Social Theory and Social Structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Bernanke, B.
(2008). “Liquidity Provision by the Federal Reserve.” (accessed January 19,
2010).
------ (2009).
“Reflections on a Year in Crisis.” <http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/
speech/bernanke20090821a.htm>
(accessed January 19, 2010).
Dequech, D.
(2001). “Confidence and Action: A Comment on Barbalet.” Journal of SocioEconomics, 29: 503-15.
Fehr, E.
(2008). “On the Economics and Biology of Trust.” Bonn, Germany, Working Paper
IZA DP No. 3895.
Fukuyama, F. (1995). Trust: The Social Virtues
and the Creation of Prosperity. London: Penguin.
Griffin, D.
and Tversky, A. (1992). “The Weighing of Evidence and the Determinants of
Confidence.” Cognitive Psychology, 24: 411-35.
Guiso, L.,
Sapienza, P., and Zingales, L. (2008). “Trusting the Stock Market.” Journal of Finance, 63/6: 2557-600.
Hardin, R.
(2001). “Conceptions and Explanations of Trust,” in K. Cook (ed.), Trust in Society. New York: Russell Sage
Foundation, 3-39.
Hart, K.
(1988). “Kinship, Contract, and Trust: The Economic Organization of Migrants in
an African Slum,” in D. Gambetta (ed.), Trust. Oxford: Blackwell, 176-83.
Kanter, R. M. (2006). Confidence: How Winning
Streaks and Losing Streaks Begin and End. New York: Three Rivers Press.
Katona, G.
(1975). Psychological
Economics.
New York: Elsevier.
Keynes, J. M.
(1915). “The Works of Bagehot.” Economic Journal, 25/99: 369-75.
------ (1936). The General Theory of Employment,
Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.
------ (1937). “The General Theory of Employment.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics,
51/2:
209-23.
Knorr Cetina,
K. and Preda, A. (eds.) (2005). The Sociology of Financial Markets. New York: Oxford
University Press.
La Porta, R.,
Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1997). “Trust in Large Organizations.”
American
Economic Review, 87: 333-8.
Lavington, F. (1922). The Trade Cycle: An
Account of the Causes Producing Rhythmical Changes in the Activity of Business. London: P. S. King &
Son.
Luhman, N.
(1988). “Familiarity, Confidence, Trust: The Problems and Alternatives,” in D.
Gambetta (ed.), Trust. Oxford: Blackwell, 94-108.
Merton, R. K.
([1948] 1968). “The Self-Fulfilling Prophecy,” In Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: The Free Press,
475-90.
Pech, W. and
Milan, M. (2009). “Behavioral Economics and the Economics of Keynes.” Journal of Socio-Economics, 38: 891-902.
Peirce, C. S.
(1991). Peirce
on Signs,
ed. J. Hoppes. Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.
Pixley, J. (2004). Emotions in Finance:
Distrust and Uncertainty in Global Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sapienza, P.
(2009). “Trusting and the Market” Talk at the Kellogg Graduate School of
Management, October 24.
Schumpeter,
J. A. (1954). History of Economic Analysis. London: Allen & Unwin.
Seligman, A.
(1997). The
Problem of Trust. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Shiller, R.
(1999). “Measuring Bubble Expectations and Investor Confidence.” Cambridge, MA:
NBER Working Paper No. 7008.
------ (2000).
Irrational
Exuberance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Simmel, G.
([1907] 1978). The Philosophy of Money. London: Routledge.
------ (1950).
The
Sociology of Georg Simmel, ed. and tr. K. Wolff. New York: The Free Press.
Smith, Adam.
([1766] 1997). “Lecture on the Influence of Commerce on Manners” In Reputation: Studies in the
Voluntary Elicitation of Good Conduct. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press,
17-20.
Swedberg, R.
(2010). “The Structure of Confidence and the Collapse of Lehman Brothers” in P.
Hirsch and M. Lounsbury (eds.), Markets on Trial: The Economic Sociology of the U.S.
Financial Crisis, Vol. 1. Bingley: Emerald Press, 67-110.
------ (2011).
“The Role of the Senses and Signs in the Economy: More on the Centrality of
Materiality.” Journal of Cultural
Economy,
12: 15-36.
Walters, A.
(1992). “Confidence” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Money and Finance, Vol. 1. London: Macmillan,
423-5.
Weber, M.
([1920] 1946). “The Protestant Sects and the Spirit of Capitalism” in H. Gerth
and C. W. Mills (eds.), From Max Weber. New York: Oxford University Press, 302-22.
Williamson, O. (1993). “Calculativeness, Trust,
and Economic Organization.” Journal
of Law and Economics, 36:
453-86.
沒有留言:
張貼留言