AARON Z. PITLUCK1
Islamic banking and finance (hereafter IBF) is a market in
formation with factious voices claiming certain economic activity as
“Shariah-compliant” or “Islamic” while other voices claim the same economic
activity to be outside of, if not contrary to, Islam. Describing Islamic
finance as a discordant chorus is a trivial ontological claim. After all, Islam
is not a centrally organized hierarchical religion, and for 40 years Islamic
scholars have engaged in print in intense debates regarding how to interpret
contemporary financial practices (Siddiqi 2007). However, this is a useful
epistemological claim, for in the presence of such factious voices making
contradictory moral and theological claims, Abend (2008) counsels the
sociologist to be metaphysically agnostic. By analyzing these competing
conceptions of control (Fligstein 1996), we can empirically investigate the
ambiguity and internal dissent regarding what constitutes IBF, and see that the
future of finance —both “conventional” and “Islamic” — is subject to dispute and
change (de Goede 2005).
Social scientists normatively invested in
critiquing financialization (the distancing of credit or capital gains from
real assets), usury (exploitative banking relationships), or the ontological
presuppositions of conventional finance have investigated contemporary IBF as
a potential alternative financial system. Many are disappointed by what they
discover. This chapter argues that although isomorphic social mechanisms push
IBF to resemble conventional finance in numerous complex and subtle ways, IBF
remains a substantively distinctive and valuable intellectual project. For
social scientists, the case of IBF demonstrates the possibilities and
constraints facing activists in reducing finan- cialization and exploitation in
economic relationships.
Before making this argument, a few preliminary remarks
are necessary. IBF originated in the early 1970s and postdates the
conventional banking sector. The origins and diffusion of IBF are intertwined not with terrorism but with the slow shifting of the world’s hegemonic center from a North-South axis to a multi-polar East-South arrangement (Imam and Kpodar 2010; Nederveen Pieterse 2011; Pollard and Samers 2007).3
432
AARON Z. PITLUCK
Table 22.1 Top 25 Countries Ranked by
Shariah-compliant Assets in 2010
|
Source: Caplen and DiVanna
(2010).
|
The chapter’s argument is organized as follows. The
first section explores the definitional anxiety surrounding IBF. The second
surveys and critiques the social science literature. I then explain why IBF so
closely resembles conventional finance, followed by a brief conclusion.
What is Islamic finance, really?
什麼是伊斯蘭金融,真的嗎?
什麼是伊斯蘭金融,真的嗎?
“What
is Islamic finance?” To answer the question is to join a contested discourse
regarding how to interpret contemporary finance from the perspective of the
Shariah (divine law). As a preliminary definition of IBF:
1) Financiers must attend to the
objects being financed. IFIs must not purchase equity in or provide credit to
products and activities prohibited by the religion.
2) Riba and gharar are prohibited. Elucidating riba is the principal exercise of
this chapter. As a working translation, riba is associated with interest, usury, and
financial transactions untied to the nonfinancial economy. Gharar is associated with
unproductive risk and exploitative information asymmetries.
3)
More broadly, Shariah discourages asceticism and
encourages the enjoyment of worldly goods from profitable trading, so long as
trades are by mutual consent and do not involve products prohibited by the
religion (e.g., alcohol or pork). Charity is obligatory. Debt is permissible so
long as it is for lawful purposes, outlined above (Vogel and Hayes 1998:
53-69).
There is considerable definitional anxiety among
practitioners of IBF. Bill Maurer (2005: 40) notes an almost ritualistic
exegesis in “almost every Islamic banking speech act or text” of what
constitutes Islamic finance and how it is or is not distinguished from what
this chapter will term “conventional” finance. This definitional anxiety is
heightened by the perception by many—both within and outside of the field—that
IBF is simply conventional finance dressed in Islamic garb. As a consequence,
for some the question becomes, “What is Islamic finance, really?”
This section argues that a defining distinction between
conventional finance and the ideal-type of IBF is riba and gharar. However, the interpretation of these two
prohibitions with respect to contemporary finance remains contested because of
the social organization of the religion and of the IBF industry. This
contestation surrounding how to interpret riba and gharar in the contemporary economy largely
explains the existing ambiguity regarding what is and what is not IBF.
Delimiting IBF: the social organization of Islam
劃定伊斯蘭銀行和金融的界限:伊斯蘭教的社會組織
劃定伊斯蘭銀行和金融的界限:伊斯蘭教的社會組織
Islam is not monolithic. The Islamic world is diverse,
with numerous traditions— Indonesian/Malay, Indo-Pakistani, Persian,
Turkic—that have little in common with the experience of the Arabian Peninsula.6
There is therefore a great deal of geographic heterogeneity in how Islam is
practiced and how communities interpret Shariah (Warde 2010).
Islamic finance is less diverse; nevertheless it is an
“elusive, contested, evolving and heterogeneous set of practices that defies
simple description or conceptualization” (Pollard and Samers 2007: 314). Sunni
Islam has four distinct schools of interpretation of Shariah. Legal
interpretations (fiqh) evolve as Shariah scholars draw on the consensus interpretations within
particular schools and time periods (ijma), interpret via careful reflection and devout
effort (ijtihad), reason by analogy from
primary sources (qiyas), or depart from tradition because of local custom (‘urf), public interest (maslaha), or overriding necessity (durura) (Vogel and Hayes 1998:
23-47). As a consequence, when a Shariah scholar or Shariah supervisory board
issues a fatwa (authoritative legal opinion)
that permits transaction X,
one should not conclude that
transaction X is “Islamic” for all parties and for all time. The ijtihads of
different scholars may legitimately vary. Moreover, if the fatwa is based on
utilitarian choice, assessments of utility can change with place and time. And
lastly, a fatwa might rest on nothing more than temporary, and changeable,
necessity. (Vogel and Hayes 1998: 41)
Broadly speaking, across diverse schools of
interpretation, virtuous profits are derived by receiving money in exchange for
providing a real asset or service. In contrast, one may not make money by
exchanging money. As a consequence, the only moral loan is as an act of
charity, where a loan is given without interest, and a needy debtor is absolved
if he or she cannot repay. One such loan is qard hasan, literally a “good loan.” Such charitable
lending is argued to be superior to charitable giving, since a needy borrower
retains his or her dignity, and loans repaid can be given out to others as
additional charity. Such loans are understood as charitable because Islam
recognizes that the lender of money is sacrificing the time value of lent
money, and the lender of property is sacrificing rent (El-Gamal 2006: 57;
Maurer 2005; Usmani 2002: 4; Vogel and Hayes 1998: 105-6; Warde 2010: 139).
When one makes money from money (i.e.,
receives money in exchange for money of the same currency, rather than in
exchange for a real asset), this is conceived of as “riba” literally meaning “increase,”
and is forbidden. There is a strong consensus among IBF practitioners that riba is a core prohibition in
economic activity and a central criteria distinguishing Islamic finance from
conventional finance. Nevertheless, since the religion’s origins in the
Arabian Peninsula, there has been debate regarding what activities are and are
not riba, as well as why riba is prohibited. This debate
regarding riba has intensified in Islamic
economics journals since the mid-1970s, the period coinciding with the birth of
the modern IBF industry (Siddiqi 2007; Warde 2010). Although riba is often equated with
“interest” or “usury,” for most IBF scholars this is either an excessively
narrow understanding of riba, or an eccentrically broad understanding of “interest”
or “usury” (El-Gamal 2003, 2006, 2007; Maurer 2001: 9, 2005; Vogel and Hayes
1998: 72-87; Warde 2010).
Gharar is less controversially defined, but interpreting its
presence or absence in contemporary finance is often contentious, particularly
in insurance products and derivative instruments. Gharar is a prohibition against
speculative transactions on uncertain or contingent objects, both to prevent
gambling on aleatory promises, and to eliminate exploitative information
asymmetries (El-Gamal 2001; Vogel and Hayes 1998: 87-93, especially 90).
Al-Zarqa defines gharar as “the sale of probable items whose existence or
characteristics are not certain, due to the risky nature which makes the trade
similar to gambling” (quoted in El-Gamal 2001: 5). Although there is great
debate among Shariah scholars in how to apply gharar to contemporary finance, “[the] majority
positions of classicalfiqh seem antithetical to a great many modern financial
transactions, since they presumptively ban all sales of goods not already both
owned and in the possession of the seller, not to mention goods that do not yet
exist” (Vogel and Hayes 1998: 93). The contested nature of how to interpret riba and gharar in contemporary finance is
therefore a fundamental cause for the continued debate on what is or is not
Islamic finance and banking.
Delimiting IBF: the social
organization of the Islamic finance industry
劃定伊斯蘭銀行和金融的界限:伊斯蘭金融業的社會組織
劃定伊斯蘭銀行和金融的界限:伊斯蘭金融業的社會組織
A second source of the ambiguity regarding how to
interpret riba and gharar in the contemporary economy
is the decentralized and opaque structure of the IBF industry. There is no
worldwide centralized Shariah board that can impose interpretations of Shariah.
Some states do have a national Shariah body that could potentially standardize
interpretations of Shariah in the field of finance, but few countries have
sought to do so, with the notable exceptions of Malaysia, Kuwait, and Pakistan
(Grais and Pellegrini 2006: 16, 33). As a consequence, every IFI must form its
own Shariah supervisory board. Applications of Shariah to financial products
and instruments therefore can and do vary between firms even within the same
country.
Shariah supervisory boards in corporations
serve two functions: appraising the IFI’s proposed new financial products and
instruments to determine whether they are permissible, and auditing ongoing
operations for Shariah-compliance. These functions can be subverted by weak
corporate governance (Chapra 2007; El-Hawary, Grais, and Iqbal 2004; Grais and
Pellegrini 2006; Kahf 2005; Nienhaus 2007; Safieddine 2009). In contrast to
external auditors in the conventional finance industry, Shariah supervisory
board members typically may hold an equity stake in the companies they
supervise. Even the AAOIFI (Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic
Financial Institutions) guidelines for Shariah supervisory boards merely
prohibit scholars from holding “significant shareholdings” rather than any
equity stake (for an excerpt of the AAOIFI guidelines, see Nienhaus 2007: 136).
To preserve the Shariah scholars’ independent judgment, ideally their
remuneration would be determined at annual shareholders’ meetings rather than
by the IFI’s management or Board of Directors.
436 AARON Z. PITLUCK
However, in practice remuneration is often delegated by shareholders at such meetings to the Board of Directors or to management, thereby short-circuiting the scholars’ insulation from influence. Strangely, the AAOIFI guidelines permit this.7
This weak corporate governance is compounded by an opaque decision-making process. In the early years of the IBF industry, the fatwas of IBF scholars were publicly accessible. Since the 1980s, fatwas are increasingly treated as proprietary information (akin to paid legal advice) and are therefore not shared with the public or shareholders.
As a consequence, clients and external Shariah experts can observe an unknown fraction of decisions made by a firm’s Shariah supervisory board, but often the process and reasoning is hidden, and fatwas that conflict with the firm’s economic interests are unpublicized and unavailable (Siddiqi 2007). Such opacity is particularly problematic in firms with weak or nonexistent external auditing of Shariah-compliance (Chapra 2007).
An evolving counterpoint to the opaque decision-making of decentralized Shariah supervisory boards is the work by intergovernmental and transnational organizations to create standard interpretations of Shariah in the IBF sector. The two perceived as most influential are the Islamic Fiqh Academy in Jeddah created by the OIC (Organization of the Islamic Conference), and the Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions (AAOIFI) in Bahrain (Warde 2010: 234-7). Although the IBF industry resists such regulatory interventions (Ghoul 2008; Grais and Pellegrini 2006), this institutional glue may become helpful to identifiably demarcate IBF from the conventional financial services industry (Fligstein 1996; White 2002).
What does the IBF field encompass?(p.436)
什麼是伊斯蘭銀行和金融的領域?
This section has argued that the considerable definitional anxiety regarding what financial products are and are not “Islamic” can be traced to the social organization of Islam and the decentralized and opaque structures determining and monitoring Shariah- compliance. In the contemporary IBF field, the least controversial products and financial instruments involve risk capital or credit for the purchase of a productive asset. Both practices can be interpreted as tethering finance to the real economy and are described in detail in the next section.
Also widely “accepted” as IBF is the Shariah-compliant slice of conventional equity markets and the fund management industry, at least as perceived by a “consensus” document produced by the Islamic Development Bank and two influential transnational industry organizations (IDB, IRTI, and IFSB 2007: xi, 41). Stock represents equity in corporations, and is therefore permitted to be purchased and sold, both in primary and secondary markets, as long as the corporation’s principal lines of business are Shariah- compliant (for details see Pitluck 2008). Pension funds and the fund management industry are compliant as long as firms invest in Shariah-compliant assets and store liquid capital in the IBF sector. Worldwide, there are approximately 700 Shariah-compliant asset management funds, located primarily in Saudi Arabia, Malaysia, and the Cayman Islands, with approximately half of funds domiciled in Saudi Arabia (Ernst & Young 2010a: 7, 52-3).
Presently there is considerable debate
regarding whether Islamic bonds and insurance products are Shariah-compliant
(IDB, IRTI, and IFSB 2007: 41). Over the past decade IFIs have raised over
$136 billion in corporate and sovereign Islamic bonds (sukuk) designed to elude riba (IIFM 2010: 6, 14, 19).
Symptomatic of the contested legitimacy of sukuk, in February 2008 the AAOIFI’s Shariah board
ruled that the majority of existing sukuk issues were not Shariah-compliant, although
the board chose to enforce its ruling only for new sukuk issues (IIFM 2010; Rethel
2011). Insurance is even more contentious, as it was once viewed as
self-evidently containing gharar. However, by 2008 there were approximately 158 takaful companies spread across the
Middle East, North Africa, and Southeast Asia claiming to offer
Shariah-compliant life and general insurance, with an additional 36
conventional institutions in Indonesia offering “takaful windows” (Ernst & Young 2010b: 37).
Nevertheless, the industry itself acknowledges that worldwide, “[t]he fiqhi [interpretations of Shariah]
differ widely, often challenging even the basic concept of takaful” (IDB, IRTI, and IFSB 2007:
36).
Outside of the above areas, contemporary
interpretations of riba and gharar interpret most modern financial
instruments—particularly derivatives—as antithetical to IBF (IDB, IRTI, and
IFSB 2007: 41). As a consequence, although complex Islamic financial
instruments are built using contemporary techniques of structured finance
(El-Gamal2005), the IBF sector was remarkably stable during the
global financial crisis of 2007-8 (Hasan and Dridi 2010). Shariah supervisory
boards had generally not permitted IFIs to purchase securitized financial
instruments such as mortgage-backed securities, as this would entail the sale
of debt. Similarly, they were generally prohibited from trading credit default
swaps, because the sale of promises entails gharar (Warde 2010: 88-9). As a consequence, IFIs
didn’t face counterparty risk from failing conventional financial institutions.
In subsequent years, growth in the IBF sector stalled not from financial
contagion, but because of reduced North-South trade and production in the
North’s real economy (e.g., Dubai’s debt crisis).8
Social
scientists seeking alternatives are disappointed
尋求替代品的社會科學家們感到失望
In recent years, a number of social scientists have
examined IBF for its emancipatory potential in restructuring the global
financial architecture. With few exceptions the exercise has left them
disappointed, leading them to make one of two arguments. Firstly, analysts
discover that the paragon forms of financing in IBF—profit and loss sharing—is
rarely practiced, and they therefore conclude that IBF fails on its own terms. Second,
analysts argue that the most common forms of financing in IBF—sales-based and
leasing contracts—are substantively identical to conventional finance, and
therefore IBF is merely a facade for conventional banking practices. In this
section I outline both arguments and critique the second.
The ideal-type of IBF is rarely practiced
伊斯蘭銀行和金融的理想类型的很少
伊斯蘭銀行和金融的理想类型的很少
Although
IBF is composed of dissonant voices, throughout the world one form of
financing—profit and loss sharing—is widely accepted as the paradigmatic form
of the IBF sector (Chapra 2007; Chong and Liu 2009; ElGindi, Said, and
Salevurakis 2009; Kamla 2009; Khan 2010; Kuran 2004; Mirakhor and Zaikdi 2007:
57; Nienhaus 2007; Zaher and Hassan 2001). “It is an ideal alternative for the
interest-based financing with far reaching effects on both production and
distribution” (Usmani 2002: 1, also see 41). This preference extends to retail
customers. In interviews with Muslim Americans regarding Islamic mortgages,
Maurer (2006: 75) finds that they have a “fondness” for profit- and loss-sharing
contracts. From the perspective of normative social science, in contrast to
conventional interest-based financing, profit- and loss-financing creates
a close coupling of the
financial and the “real” economy. Financiers are encouraged to invest in
promising projects, to share profits and losses with entrepreneurs and, in so
doing, promote development. Money is to be tied to real (material) assets to
make them grow; it cannot be used as a commodity in and of itself or used as
collateral. (Pollard and Samers 2007: 314)
IBF practitioners attempt to create contemporary
“Islamic” variants of conventional banking products and financial instruments
by drawing on, modifying, and concatenating historic financial contracts that
classical fiqh scholars had judged to be
permissible. One of these classical contracts is musharaka, Arabic for “sharing.” In IBF, a musharaka contract creates a joint
enterprise in which a bank and a firm are partners who share the profits or
losses arising from the joint venture. The most commonly practiced profit- and
loss-sharing contracts in the IBF industry are mudaraba contracts where one party (the bank)
invests capital in an entrepreneur’s business, thereby becoming a limited liability
partner. Both contracts are typically written so that the bank withdraws from
the partnership gradually, or upon the fulfillment of specific conditions. If
both partners successfully satisfy the contract, at the contract’s end the
entrepreneur is the sole owner (Usmani 2002: 12-17; Warde 2010: 145-9).
Despite the theological and ideological
importance of IFIs entering profit- and loss- sharing arrangements with
clients, it is well documented that very little of the IBF sector’s capital is
invested in such products. As early as 1984, only 14 percent of Pakistan’s
Islamic banks held assets categorized as mudaraba or musharaka. In 1986, the Central Bank of Iran reported
that mudaraba and musharaka accounted for 38 percent of
assets (Kuran 2004: 9). An examination of assets in the ten largest Islamic
banks, between 1994 and 1996, revealed that on average they held only 14
percent of assets in profit- and loss- sharing arrangements (Khan 2010: 809).
In an analysis of 81 private Islamic banks between 1994 and 1995, Yousef (2005:
65) found that the percentage of financing made up of profit- and loss-sharing
contracts averages 14 percent in the Middle East and North Africa, 30 percent
in East Asia, 8 percent in South Asia, and 44 percent in sub-Saharan Africa.
Yousef also noted that variation within countries and between countries in the
same region is small. To the degree that we equate such activity with the idea
of financial
institutions forming partnerships with
entrepreneurs in the real economy, and therefore as a contrast to financialization
in the economy, even the above figures may be overstating the size of profit-
and loss-sharing activities in the IBF sector. This is because many IBF
institutions categorize portfolio management as mudaraba transactions, even though this “investment”
is channeled not to businesses in the real economy but into secondary asset
markets such as Shariah-compliant stocks (Warde 2010: 149).
In sum, building on the influential work of Kuran
(2004), over the past few years social scientists such as Chong and Liu (2009),
Kamla (2009), and Khan (2010) have evaluated IBF as an alternative to
conventional finance, determined that IBF practitioners perceive profit- and
loss-sharing instruments as paradigmatic Islamic transactions, and then
documented that the contemporary IBF sector engages in few of these transactions.
All depart disappointed.
IBF as practiced is
substantively identical to conventional finance
The majority of IBF financing is conducted not on the
basis of profit and loss sharing, but as a finance component in a sale or
lease. The most common such sale-based instrument is murabaha (Khan 2010). Historically, a
murabaha contract was a spot market
negotiation between a buyer and seller over the seller’s profit, rather than a
negotiation over the price itself. This “cost plus” transaction would allow
buyers ignorant of a good’s cost to negotiate on equal terms with the seller
(Warde 2010: 140).
In the contemporary IBF industry, this
contract has been adapted to become a mode of financing. A client requests her
bank to purchase an asset on her behalf, and then the client purchases the
asset from the bank in installments. The bank is interpreted as improving the
asset by giving it a new characteristic—the ability to purchase it using a
deferred payment. This improvement of the asset, being of value to the client,
permits the bank to charge a higher price (Usmani 2002: 46). This transparent
increment above cost is often called “profit” or “service charge,” but never
“interest.” A second sale-based form of financing is ijara, which is “virtually
identical to conventional leasing: the bank leases an asset to a [client] in
exchange for a specified rent.” (Warde 2010: 144).
Both murabaha and ijara involve the purchase or use of an asset (not money),
and are therefore understood to avoid riba, in the sense of money paid for money lent
(Warde 2010; Wilson 2008). Murabaha is interpreted as permissible because it
link[s] extension of credit
to a unique transfer of goods from a third party to the customer, and in doing
so they make a meaningful connection with a credit sale of goods . . . A
conventional loan, by way of contrast, need have no connection with any
economic or legal event beyond the customer’s undertaking to repay. (Vogel and
Hayes 1998: 143)
Both murabaha and ijara are argued to resist financialization—the distancing
of credit or capital gains from real assets.
Although murabaha financing is widely approved by Shariah
supervisory boards, its legitimacy has become paper thin because, in practice,
these contracts often have only a tenuous connection with the trading of a real
asset. The connection may be frayed in two ways. The first is the connection
between the bank and the asset. Murabaha loans inherently have two risks above and beyond that
of a conventional loan: a) the risk to the bank of purchasing an asset that a
client might decide not to repurchase, and b) the risk that the asset is
damaged prior to the sale to the client. To minimize these two risks, some (but
not all) Shariah supervisory boards allow banks to delegate the client as their
purchasing agent. The client as agent purchases the asset on behalf of the bank
and then immediately (as an agent) sells the asset to himself. As a consequence,
the bank plays no entrepreneurial role in selecting or buying the asset, and
“owns” the asset for mere seconds before “selling” it. In such common
contracts, the connection between the bank and the asset is tenuous (El-Gamal
2006; Usmani 2002; Vogel and Hayes 1998).
Second, the asset’s connection to the client
can be even more tenuous. Consider a scenario in which a client wants cash and
does not want or need an asset, so that the asset is only a ruse to get Islamic
financing. For example, a client in need of $10,000 can request the bank to
purchase an asset worth $10,000 and then make a deferred sale of the asset to
the client for $10,000 plus the profit markup. The client can then immediately
obtain the desired cash by selling the asset for $10,000 minus transaction
costs (Vogel and Hayes 1998: 142-3, 177).9 When assets are wholly
liquid and fungible, and can be cheaply bought and sold, such as silver, or
more controversially, stock in a corporation, the connection between the
client and the asset can be quite tenuous—the client never takes physical
possession of the asset, and may “own” it for mere seconds before selling it
for nearly the same price as the bank had (for mere seconds) “purchased” it. In
such a stratagem, murabaha becomes “only a device to escape interest and not the
ideal instrument for carrying out the real economic objectives of Islam”
(Usmani 2002: 41).
Noted critics of IBF, such as Timur Kuran
(2004), have called murabaha financing an “ancient ruse” (15) and merely a “semantic
difference” (10) where debt contracts are Islamicized by using Arabic terms and
replacing the word “interest” with terms such as “service charge,”
“administrative fee,” “markup,” or “profit.” The “semantic difference” between
Islamic and conventional finance is also demonstrated by comparing numbers
generated by conventional and Islamic products. Maurer (2008: 70) asks, “Why is
an Islamic mortgage ‘Islamic’ if the calculation of the payment structure and
schedule is identical to that of a conventional interest-based mortgage?” Both
Maurer (2006: 37; 2008) and Khan (2010) use amortization tables of Islamic and
conventional mortgages in order to demonstrate them to be materially identical.
Such similar calculations are generated because many Islamic banks benchmark
their service charges to an international benchmark interest rate (Libor) or
to the interest rates charged by competitors (El-Gamal 2006: 74-80).
Taken together, these observations have led
many social scientists, IBF practitioners, and prospective and current IBF
clients to argue that Islamic finance is merely a facade for conventional
finance (Chong and Liu 2009; Kamla 2009; Khan 2010). A variant of this line of
thought argues that Islamic finance products are nearly identical to those in
conventional finance, except that they are economically inefficient, have high
transaction costs, and bear additional economic and legal risks (El-Gamal
2006, 2008; Kuran 2004). Similar debates take place among Islamic economists
and IBF practitioners (Maurer 2005, 2006, 2008; Siddiqi 2007; Wilson 2008:
192).
Maurer (2005) briefly reviews these arguments but
ultimately rejects the question of whether IBF is distinctive from conventional
finance. Instead, he displaces the question by pointing out that the same debate
takes place among IBF practitioners at a more sophisticated level of analysis
and remains unresolved (also see Maurer 2001).10 Pollard and Samers
(2007) are also wary of taking a position, in part because they worry about the
“enduring, largely unconscious Eurocentrism of European and North American
knowledge production” (324). They are particularly skeptical of modernist and
econo- mistic discourses that conceive of Islamic finance as an inefficient,
alternative, or peripheral form of finance that will ultimate replicate or be
replaced by conventional finance.
Critique 批判
In the next section, I will propose an argument for why
the distinctive IBF sector so closely resembles conventional finance. Before I
can do so, however, I must dispose of three arguments in the social science
literature that are used to argue that Islamic finance is substantively
identical to conventional finance.
First, a number of authors compare the
amortization schedules between conventional and Islamic products and find them
to be substantively similar or identical (e.g., Khan 2010; Maurer 2006: 37;
2008). Such amortization calculations are self-evidently an important
characteristic of these financial products, particularly for clients who have a
choice between conventional and Shariah-compliant products. However, this
argument confuses the financial products for formulas, when in fact financial
products are legal contracts detailing rights and responsibilities of
transacting parties to an asset. Financial products require far more of
transacting parties than mere agreement to an amortization schedule.
I suggest that a superior exercise would be
to compare the language of Islamic and conventional contracts. When this
exercise is conducted, it is again easy to be mistaken and interpret IBF as a
facade, for much of the language can be identical. For example, Islamic home
mortgages in the United States can have pages of language identical to a
conventional home mortgage; both contracts contain terms inimical to Islamic
finance such as “loan,” “interest,” “lender,” and “borrower” (Maurer 2006: 48,
50)“ However, in contrast to conventional mortgages, Islamic mortgages include additional contractual language
mandating specific actions, including a redefinition of terms such as
“interest” in the accompanying mortgage document (Maurer 2006). This point is
generalizable: Islamic financial products are typically more complicated than
conventional financial products insofar as they constitute multiple contracts
in order to create multiple sales, create special purpose vehicles, and other
legal exotica (El-Gamal 2006). If financial products are understood as legal contracts,
Islamic financial products cannot be confused for conventional financial
products.
Second, the facade argument ignores the
intentions and epistemologies of participants (Maurer 2006; Swedberg 2007).
For example, clients and prospective customers currently desire to have Islamic
products closely resemble the cost structure of conventional products, and yet
be distinctively Islamic (Elfakhani, Zbib, and Ahmed 2007). As an American
Islamic mortgage company explains in its promotional brochure, “We do not
change the math. We change the way we do business” (Maurer 2006: 52; 2008: 70).
In interviews with Muslim Americans, Maurer (2006: 74-84) found that they
valued mortgages (and banks) approved by prominent scholars, and valued
Islamic banks that treated them formally and bureaucratically, in a fashion
similar to the conventional banking system, while at the same time offering a
product that felt “processual, social, and collaborative” (75). Rather than
perceiving Islamic mortgages as problematically similar to conventional
mortgages, there is evidence that customers simultaneously desire such
similarities while also craving an “Islamic difference.”
The facade argument also ignores the intentions of IBF
scholars who write into Islamic financial products’ contracts required
behaviors that are wholly absent in conventional finance. For example, recall
that a key characteristic distinguishing murabaha contracts from interest-based lending is
that the former must fund a real asset (El-Gamal 2006; Usmani 2002; Vogel and
Hayes 1998). IBF scholars such as Usmani (2002: 65) therefore write into these
contracts that the bank must take “all necessary steps” “to make sure that the
client really intends to purchase a commodity.”12 He provides three
examples of such steps:
1. Instead of providing funds to
the client to purchase the commodity, the bank should provide funds directly to
the supplier;
2. If the client must be
entrusted with the funds, the bank should require evidence that the commodity
was purchased by examining invoices and similar documents;
3.
Where funds are entrusted but invoices are not
available, “the financing institution should arrange for physical inspection
of the purchased commodity.” (Usmani 2002: 65)
My point is simply that intentions such as these,
documented in Islamic financial products, are substantively different than in conventional
products. Certainly many details found in contracts—Islamic or conventional—may
in practice be poorly implemented, avoided, or even unknown to signatories. How
contracts are enacted is an empirical question that partly reflects the balance
of power between IFIs and their Shariah supervisory boards, as well as the
enforcement of contract law in the country. Unfortunately, the poor corporate
governance and opacity of IFIs with respect to Shariah-compliance, discussed in
the previous section, inhibits an empirical assessment of whether IFIs are or
are not fulfilling their contractual obligations to be Shariah-compliant.
In summary, although the formulas and fee structures in
Islamic and conventional financial products may be by design quite similar, the
physical embodiment of financial instruments in words, the intentions behind
those words, and some of the financial practices required of the transacting
parties are substantively different. For sociologists, the efforts that IFIs
and Shariah supervisory boards make to ensure that each client requesting
credit “really intends to purchase a commodity” provides a demonstration of the
thorny conceptual and pragmatic challenges required for any agent to prevent
financialization.
Why
does IBF closely resemble conventional finance?
為什麼伊斯蘭銀行和金融非常類似於傳統的金融?
為什麼伊斯蘭銀行和金融非常類似於傳統的金融?
Why is IBF—although distinctive—nevertheless similar in
many respects to conventional finance? Drawing on DiMaggio and Powell’s (1983)
typology of isomorphic change, I analytically identify three mechanisms
promoting similarities between Islamic and conventional finance.13
The first mechanism is coercive isomorphism resulting from formal and
informal pressures by other organizations, as well as broader cultural
expectations (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). In our case, the strongest
structurating force is a secular legal system that has coevolved with an
interest-based financial services industry. Each country’s extant regulatory
structure and legal precedents pose unique challenges for the IBF sector. The
applied literature is filled with complex regulatory issues, but a simple
illustration will suffice.
In many countries, regulators require banks
to assure full repayment of account holders’ deposits; in contrast to profit-
and loss-sharing banking, losses are not legally permitted. When the Islamic
Bank of Britain sought a banking license, it desired to offer a profit- and
loss-sharing account (mudaraba) where the customer receives profits and losses based
on a risk-sharing formula, rather than a risk-free interest rate, as required
by local interpretations of Shariah (Plews 2005). However the Financial
Services Agency (FSA) requires that all UK deposit holders be assured full
repayment unless the bank is insolvent. The compromise that the Islamic Bank of
Britain and the FSA reached was that if the bank’s risk-sharing formula
suggested that customers suffer losses, the bank would nevertheless be required
to offer full repayment of the capital (in accordance with FSA regulations);
however, customers may elect to accept less than full repayment and instead
accept the amount determined by the risk-sharing formula (in accordance with
local interpretations of Shariah) (Fiennes 2005; Plews 2005). In this
putatively successful resolution, the Islamic Bank of Britain offers profit- and
loss-sharing deposit accounts to depositors that legally cannot lose money
without the ex post consent of depositors.M
To date, only a few countries have sought to
circumvent their national legal system’s coercive isomorphism by enacting
Islamic banking laws: for example, Indonesia, Iran, Malaysia, Pakistan, Sudan,
Turkey, the United Arab Emirates, and Yemen (El-Hawary, Grais, and Iqbal 2004: 26).
444 AARON Z. PITLUCK
However, it is an empirical question whether such legislation merely reproduces the conventional banking laws with minor alterations or whether it addresses larger epistemological differences between the Islamic and conventional financial systems (cf., Rethel 2011).
The second social force encouraging Islamic and conventional finance to resemble one another is competitive isomorphism. As organizations compete with one another (and seek to minimize competition by forming market niches), the organizations within a market niche progressively resemble one another, either by learning from successful competitors and their products, or because dissimilar organizations or products do not survive market competition (DiMaggio and Powell 1983; Fligstein 1996; Hannan and Freeman 1977). A frequent argument in the literature is that the IBF sector is a small niche in a competitive industry. In order to compete for clients and meet the demands of shareholders, the fees charged to IBF clients will rapidly converge on the interest-based fees charged to clients in the conventional sector.
Yousef (2005) has made a similar point by arguing that it is unrealistic to expect the IBF sector to be primarily constituted by profit- and loss-sharing contracts when this form of financing is so costly in the conventional sector (also see Kuran 2004). Partly to insulate Islamic banks from such competition (as well as to resolve numerous corporate governance problems plaguing the IBF sector), Mahmoud El-Gamal (2007) has argued that the IBF sector should pursue mutualization (i.e., become cooperatively owned by its customers, for example by becoming a credit union or building society). ^
A third form of isomorphic change is mimetic processes. As a consequence of uncertainty (and risk aversion), organizations may model themselves and their products on preexisting organizations and products (DiMaggio and Powell 1983). As a relatively new industry with rapid product innovation, there is a great deal of uncertainty regarding what clients want. For example, Maurer (2006) investigates how Muslim Americans interpret two kinds of Islamic mortgage products and finds that these interpretations are quite different than each firm’s understanding of their clients as well as their own marketing. Moreover, clients’ knowledge of financial markets is shaped by their experience with the conventional banking sector, and this in turn shapes their expectations for niche markets, including the IBF sector.
An additional source of uncertainty is whether new IBF products can meet the requirements of two demanding constituencies with very different criteria: the Shariah supervisory board and market regulators. Each financial product must be crafted so that it can satisfy Shariah boards (e.g., by demonstrating that a transaction is not an interest- bearing loan). However, the same product must also satisfy regulators (e.g., by demonstrating that there is no legal difference between this product and standard interest-bearing lending) (El-Gamal 2008: 198). In all financial innovation there is a risk that the product or financial instrument will not be able to pass both constituencies.
This uncertainty — combined with the uncertainty regarding what clients desire — is a powerful mimetic process, pushing Islamic financial products to resemble conventional financial products.
Conclusion (p.445)
To return to the chapter’s title: Is the Islamic
banking and finance (IBF) market a promising alternative to conventional
finance, or merely a religious facade to market products to the pious? I have
demonstrated that the question is itself warranted. There is considerable
definitional anxiety among academics, practitioners, and clients regarding how
and whether IBF is substantively different than conventional finance. Indeed, I
argue that powerful isomorphic social mechanisms push IBF to resemble conventional
finance in numerous complex and subtle ways. Nevertheless, IBF as currently
practiced remains a substantively and intellectually distinctive alternative to
conventional financial organizations, instruments, and practices.
Given that the market’s global size is estimated to be
between $822 and $1,300 billion, this makes it one of the world’s largest moral
projects seeking to reshape economic relationships. That said, sociologists
must keep in mind that much of what makes IBF a distinctive intellectual
project (such as riba and gharar) imperfectly overlaps with our own theoretical
concepts, such as financialization (cf., Alatas 2000). I suggest that as hegemony
slowly shifts from a North-South axis to an East-South multipolar arrangement,
it would be prudent for sociologists to contemplate IBF’s contested concepts
within its own discourse (Imam and Kpodar 2010; Nederveen Pieterse 2011;
Pollard and Samers 2007; Warde 2010). In a future, more multipolar sociology of
finance, riba would be discussed without
translation, and Mufti Usmani might be routinely found in bibliographies
between Professors Swedberg and White.
Notes
1. This research was partially
sponsored by Budapesti Kozep-Europai Egyetem Alapitvany (CEU BPF). The views
expressed in this chapter are those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect the views of Central European University Foundation Budapest.
2. In the three years following
the terrorist actions of September 11, 2001, most (67 percent) articles in the
mainstream media regarding IBF mentioned a link with terrorism (Ali and Syed
2010: 34), particularly through IBFs’ charitable contributions. Subsequent
investigations have found this characterization of the industry to be
unwarranted (de Goede 2008:
227-9)-
3. IBF originated in the early
1970s, fueled by the quadrupling of oil prices in 1973-4. Its principal
intellectual and institutional support arose from debates within the
Organization of the Islamic Conference (OIC) to reform the monetary and
financial system to conform with Islamic ethics, as well as in larger debates
within the United Nations for a New International Economic Order (Warde 2010:
70-113).
4. Only Iran has a wholly
Islamic financial system. Pakistan attempted one in 1985 before transitioning
into a dual financial system over the past decade, and pre-secession Sudan
attempted one between 1983 and 1986, and in the northern provinces since 1991
(Said 2005; Warde 2010: 114-25).
5. In Caplen and DiVannas (2010)
dataset, one third of IFIs do not publish financial data (nor are they required
to do so by their national regulators), and those that do provide data lagged
by several quarters or even years.
6. Arab Muslims are a minority
(200 million) of the estimated 1.6 billion Muslims in the world. The countries
with the ten largest Muslim populations are, in descending order: Indonesia,
Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, Egypt, Nigeria, Iran, Turkey, Algeria, and Morocco
(Pew Research Center 2011).
7. A 1989 survey of Shariah
supervisory boards in Islamic banks found that 29 percent of board members’
remuneration were determined by the Board of Directors, and 4 percent by
management (Vogel and Hayes 1998: 49).
8. Dubai’s iconic debt crisis in
late 2009 was unrelated to its bid to become an Islamic financial center.
Approximately 90 percent of the debt was from the conventional sector, not from
IFIs (Timmons 2009). Rather, Dubai’s insolvency was caused by the predictable
collapse of a national real estate asset bubble. Significantly, it is
East-South trade with India and China that is driving Dubai’s current recovery
(Nederveen Pieterse 2010; Zubairi 2006).
9. When banks knowingly use such
fungible assets to provide cash to clients, this is known as a “bank tawarroq” and is widely practiced in
the Gulf States. It is considered by some IBF scholars as a permissible but not
advisable economic transaction (Warde 2010: 143-4).
10. “To put it another way, the
metalevel debate between [social scientists] has already been anticipated (and
exhausted) in metalevel debates” among IBF practitioners (Maurer 2005: 71).
11. This identical language is
due to the role of agencies like Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac that standardize
mortgage forms and paperwork (Maurer 2006), a nice example of coercive
isomorphism discussed below in the main text.
12. I have chosen to detail
Usmani at length because his intentions are institutionalized in Shariah
supervisory boards throughout the world. He holds the chair on the Shariah
Council of three influential standard-setting international bodies: the
Accounting and Auditing Organization for Islamic Financial Institutions
(AAOIFI), the International Islamic Rating Agency (IIRA), and the Central Bank
of Bahrain. Additionally, he is the chair of ten Shariah supervisory boards in
Pakistan, the United Arab Emirates, and Switzerland (Usmani 2011).
13. DiMaggio and Powell (1983)
also discuss a fourth form of structuration, normative isomorphism, in which
forms resemble one another because of the professionalization process. I do
not observe this in the IBF industry, perhaps because the professionalization
process of IBF scholars is at an early stage of development (Chapra 2007; Ghoul
2008; Kahf 2005).
14.
In practice, IFIs competing with conventional banks
cannot allow even small losses without a run on the bank, and therefore IFIs
typically implement so-called “profit smoothing,” so that depositors’ returns
closely track competitors’ interest-based accounts rather than periodically
experiencing losses. This introduces numerous corporate governance and
conflicts of interest issues (see Nienhaus 2007: 130-2, 141; Safieddine 2009)
References
Abend, G. (2008). “Two Main Problems in the Sociology of Morality.” Theory and Society, 37/2: 87-125.
Alatas, S. H.
(2000). “Intellectual Imperialism: Definition, Traits, and Problems.” Southeast Asian Journal of
Social Science, 28/1: 23-45.
Ali, S. N. and
Syed, A. R. (2010). “Post-9/11 Perceptions of Islamic Finance.” International Research
Journal of Finance and Economics, 39: 27-39.
Caplen, B. and
DiVanna, J. (2010). “Top 500 Islamic Financial Institutions.” The Banker. <http://www.thebanker.com> (accessed November 24,
2010).
Chapra, M. U.
(2007). “Challenges Facing the Islamic Finance Industry,” in M. K. Hassan and
M. K. Lewis (eds.), Handbook of Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 325-57.
Chong, B. S.
and Liu, M.-H. (2009). “Islamic Banking: Interest-Free or Interest-Based?” Pacific-Basin Finance
Journal,
17: 125-44.
de Goede, M.
(2005). Virtue,
Fortune and Faith: A Genealogy of Finance. Minneapolis, MN: University of Minnesota
Press.
----- (2008).
“Money, Media and the Anti-Politics of Terrorist Finance.” European Journal of
Cultural Studies, 11/3: 289-310.
DiMaggio, P.
and Powell, W. W. (1983). “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism
and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields.” American Sociological Review, 48/2: 147-60.
El-Gamal, M.
A. (2001). “An Economic Explication of the Prohibition of Gharar in Classical Islamic
Jurisprudence.” Paper presented at the 4th International Conference on Islamic
Economics. <http://www.ruf.rice.edu/~elgamal/files/gharar.pdf> (accessed August 22,
2011).
----- (2003).
“ ‘Interest’ and the Paradox of Contemporary Islamic Law and Finance.” Fordham
International Law Journal, 27/1: 108-49.
----- (2006). Islamic Finance: Law, Economics, and
Practice.
Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
----- (2007). “Mutualization of Islamic Banks,” in
M. K. Hassan and M. K. Lewis (eds.),
Handbook of
Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 310-24.
----- (2008).
“The Tradeoff between Brand-Name Distinctiveness and Convergence.” Berkeley
Journal of Middle Eastern and Islamic
Law, 1/2:
183-201.
El-Hawary, D.,
Grais, W., and Iqbal, Z. (2004). “Regulating Islamic Financial Institutions:
The Nature of the Regulated.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No.
3227.
Elfakhani, S.
M., Zbib, I. J., and Ahmed, Z. U. (2007). “Marketing of Islamic Financial
Products,” in M. K. Hassan and M. K. Lewis (eds.), Handbook of Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 116-27.
ElGindi, T.,
Said, M., and Salevurakis, J. W. (2009). “Islamic Alternatives to Purely
Capitalist Modes of Finance: A Study of Malaysian Banks from 1999 to 2006.” Review of Radical Political
Economics,
41/4: 516-38.
Ernst & Young (2010a). Islamic
Funds and Investments Report 2010: Post Crisis: Waking Up to an Investor-Driven
World.
Dubai, UAE: MEGA Brands.
----- (2010b). The World Takaful Report 2010:
Managing Performance in a Recovery. Dubai,
UAE: MEGA
Brands.
Fiennes, T.
(2005). “The View from the Regulators in the United Kingdom,” in S. Jaffer
(ed.), Islamic
Retail Banking and Finance: Global Challenges and Opportunities. London: Euromoney Books,
190-4.
Fligstein, N. (1996).
“Markets as Politics: A Political-Cultural Approach to Market Institutions.” American Sociological Review, 61/4: 656-73.
Ghoul, W. A.
(2008). “Shariah Scholars and Islamic Finance: Towards a More Objective and
Independent Shariah-Compliance Certification of Islamic Financial Products.” Review of Islamic Economics, 12/2: 87-104.
Grais, W. and
Pellegrini, M. (2006). “Corporate Governance and Shariah Compliance in
Institutions Offering Islamic Financial Services.” World Bank Policy Research
Working Paper No. 4054.
Hannan, M. T.
and Freeman, J. (1977). “The Population Ecology of Organizations.” American Journal of
Sociology,
82/5: 929-64.
Hasan, M. and
Dridi, J. (2010). “The Effects of the Global Crisis on Islamic and Conventional
Banks: A Comparative Study.” IMF Working Paper No. WP/10/201.
IDB, IRTI, and
IFSB (Islamic Development Bank, Islamic Research and Training Institute, and
Islamic Financial Services Board) (2007). “Islamic Financial Services Industry
Development: Ten Year Framework and Strategies.” Policy Dialogue Paper.
(accessed July 24, 2011).
IIFM
(International Islamic Financial Market) (2010). Sukuk Report (1st edn). <www.iifm.net> (accessed August 8, 2011).
Imam, P. and
Kpodar, K. (2010). “Islamic Banking: How Has It Diffused?” IMF Working Paper
No. WP/10/195.
Kahf, M.
(2005). “Islamic Banks: The Rise of a New Power Alliance of Wealth and Shari’a
Scholarship,” in C. M. Henry and R. Wilson (eds.), The Politics of Islamic
Finance.
Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press, 17-36.
Kamla, R.
(2009). “Critical Insights into Contemporary Islamic Accounting.” Critical Perspectives on
Accounting,
20/8: 921-32.
Khan, F.
(2010). “How ‘Islamic’ Is Islamic Banking?” Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization, 76/3: 805-20.
Kuran, T.
(2004). Islam
and Mammon: The Economic Predicaments of Islamism. Princeton, NJ, and Oxford: Princeton
University Press.
Maurer, B. (2001).
“Engineering an Islamic Future: Speculations on Islamic Financial
Alternatives.” Anthropology Today, 17/1: 8-11.
----- (2005). Mutual
Life, Limited: Islamic Banking, Alternative Currencies, Lateral Reason.
Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
----- (2006). Pious Property: Islamic Mortgages in
the United States. New York: Russell Sage Press.
----- (2008).
“Resocializing Finance? Or Dressing It in Mufti?” Journal of Cultural Economy,
1/1: 65-78.
Mirakhor, A.
and Zaikdi, I. (2007). “Profit-and-Loss Sharing Contracts in Islamic Finance,”
in M. K. Hassan and M. K. Lewis (eds.), Handbook of Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 49-63.
Nederveen
Pieterse, J. (2010). “Views from Dubai: Oriental Globalization Revisited.” Encounters, 2: 15-37.
----- (2011).
“Global Rebalancing: Crisis and the East-South Turn.” Development and Change,
42/1: 22-48.
Nienhaus, V.
(2007). “Governance of Islamic Banks,” in M. K. Hassan and M. K. Lewis (eds.), Handbook of Islamic Banking. Cheltenham, UK and
Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar, 128-43.
Pew Research
Center. (2011). The Future of the Global Muslim Population: Projections for 2010-2030. <http://pewforum.org/The-Future-of-the-Global-Muslim-Population.aspx> (accessed July 24,
2011).
Pitluck, A.
Z. (2008). “Moral Behavior in Stock Markets: Islamic Finance and Socially
Responsible Investment,” in K. E. Browne and B. L. Milgram (eds.), Economics and Morality:
Anthropological Approaches. Lanham, MD: AltaMira Press, Rowman & Littlefield
Publishers,
233-55.
Plews, T.
(2005). “Establishing Islamic Banks in the West: The Case of the Islamic Bank
of Britain,” in S. Jaffer (ed.), Islamic Retail Banking and Finance: Global Challenges
and Opportunities. London: Euromoney Books, 31-9.
Pollard, J.
and Samers, M. (2007). “Islamic Banking and Finance: Postcolonial Political
Economy and the Decentring of Economic Geography.” Transactions of the Institute
of British Geographers, 32/3: 313-30.
Rethel, L.
(2011). “Whose Legitimacy? Islamic Finance and the Global Financial Order.” Review of International
Political Economy, 18/1: 75-98.
Safieddine,
A. (2009). “Islamic Financial Institutions and Corporate Governance: New
Insights for Agency Theory.” Corporate Governance: An International Review, 17/2: 142-58.
Said, P.
(2005). “The View from the Regulators in Pakistan,” in S. Jaffer (ed.), Islamic Retail Banking and
Finance: Global Challenges and Opportunities. London: Euromoney Books, 195-202.
Siddiqi, M.
N. (2007). “Shari’ah, Economics and the Progress of Islamic Finance: The Role
of Shari’ah Experts.” IIUM Journal of Economics and Management, 15/1: 93-113.
Swedberg, R.
(2007). “Max Weber’s Interpretive Economic Sociology.” American Behavioral
Scientist,
50/8: 1035-55.
Timewell, S.
and DiVanna, J. (2009). “Top 500 Islamic Financial Institutions,” The Banker, November: 1-30.
Timmons, H.
(2009). “Dubai Crisis Tests Laws of Islamic Financing.” The New York Times, December 1: B4.
Usmani, M. T.
(2002). An
Introduction to Islamic Finance. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
----- (2011).
“Profile.” <http://www.muftitaqiusmani.com> (accessed August 13,
2011).
Vogel, F. E.
and Hayes, S. L. (1998). Islamic Law and Finance: Religion, Risk, and Return. Boston, MA: Kluwer Law
International.
Warde, I.
(2010). Islamic
Finance in the Global Economy (2nd edn). Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.
White, H. C.
(2002). Markets
from Networks: Socioeconomic Models of Production. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
University Press.
Wilson, R.
(2008). “Islamic Economics and Finance.” World Economics, 9/1: 177-95.
Yousef, T. M.
(2005). “The Murabaha Syndrome in Islamic Finance: Laws, Institutions and
Politics,” in C. M. Henry & R. Wilson (eds.), The Politics of Islamic Finance. Edinburgh: Edinburgh
University Press, 63-80.
Zaher, T. S.
and Hassan, M. K. (2001). “A Comparative Literature of Islamic Finance and
Banking.” Financial
Markets, Institutions & Instruments, 10/4: 155-99.
Zubairi, S.
(2006). “Home Finance Schemes in the UAE: A Case Study,” in S. Jaffer (ed.), Islamic Retail Banking and
Finance: Global Challenges and Opportunities. London: Euromoney Books, 88-97.
沒有留言:
張貼留言