CHAPTER 16 THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REGIME AND DOMESTIC POLITICAL ECONOMY: THE ORIGIN OF THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS
The factors that have led to the global financial crisis
consist of both domestic and international ones.
The domestic factors include
financial innovation, deregulation, and corporate greed. The adoption of
adjustable-rate mortgages, mortgage-backed security, collateralized debt obligations,
and credit default swaps have enlarged the creation of credit. The passage of
the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act in 1999 repealed part of the Glass-Steagall Act of
1933, and reduced the separation between commercial banks and investment banks.
The relaxation of the net capital rule in 2004 enabled investment banks to
increase their debts, and the lack of regulation in the shadow banking system
has allowed them to take on more debt (Campbell 2010; Davis 2009; Krippner 2005,
2009). Risk-taking behaviors have resulted in huge corporate debts for
financial institutions, and overborrowing by consumers and households has led
to the substantial increase of US household debt (Fligstein and Goldstein
2010).
The international factors
involve the global glut of savings, which refers to overaccumulated capital by
both export-oriented and resource-rich countries, and the global glut of
liquidity, which refers to excessive money supply, especially in the United
States. The inflows of capital from over-saved countries elevated the real
exchange rate for the United States. This led to shrinking of US sectors that
produce tradable goods and services. The Federal Reserve Board cut the interest
rate to promote economic growth and prevent unemployment. This low interest
rate led to an excess demand for tradable goods and services (Bernanke 2005;
Greenspan 2008; Wolf 2008). Meanwhile, the oversupply of liquidity caused low
real interest rates, which led to a rapid growth of credit to American
consumers and a collapse of US household savings. The excess spending generated
huge trade deficits and corresponding outflows of dollars. When the dollar was
weakened, floating currencies were forced up to uncompetitive levels while
pegged currencies were kept down by open- ended foreign currency intervention.
This led to a massive accumulation of foreign currency reserves that
eventually came to the United States (Duncan 2003).
I argue that in order to understand the origins of the
global financial crisis, we need to explore the driving forces behind the
formation of these domestic and international factors. This chapter highlights
the impact of postwar international monetary regimes on the domestic political
economy in the United States. It demonstrates that the dollar’s key currency
status and US payment deficits to supply liquidity have created both the seigniorage
problem in the mechanism of liquidity creation and the benign neglect problem
in the mechanism of adjustment. These institutional defects in the postwar
international monetary regimes, moreover, have affected the United States in
three distinctive ways. First, the Federal government has regarded its policy
autonomy as a top priority and pursued its policy goals with heavy debt
financing. The resulting budget deficits and Federal debts were the major
sources of the global glut of liquidity. Second, the US financial industry has
emphasized its competitiveness in credit creation, securitizing various assets
in society, lending out money with high leverage, and escaping from government
regulation. This contributed directly to changes that accounted for the outbreak
of the subprime loan crisis. Third, affected by the dollar’s key currency
status, the US manufacturing industry led the development of global production.
This nurtured the global glut of saving in export-oriented countries and OPEC
(Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries). As multinational
corporations invested heavily overseas, the job-creating capacity of US
manufacturing was seriously weakened.
本章重點討論戰後國際貨幣制度對美國國內政治經濟的影響,說明美元關鍵貨幣的地位和美國收支赤字提供的流動性,產生了在流動性創造機制的鑄幣稅問題和調整機制的善意忽略問題。
這些制度缺陷在戰後國際貨幣制度,在三個特別的方式影響美國
首先,聯邦政府將政策自主權視為優先考量目標,用債務融資追求政策目標,結果造成預算赤字和聯邦債務成為全球流動性過剩的主要來源。
其次,美國金融產業一直強調信用創造的競爭力,證券化社會不同的資產、高槓桿的借出貨幣,以及逃避政府的監管,這直接導致說明了次貸危機的爆發。
第三,受美元關鍵貨幣地位的影響,美國的製造業領導全球製造的發展,也支持了出口導向的國家和石油輸出組織OPEC全球過剩的儲蓄,隨著跨國公司大量投資海外,美國製造業的工作創造能力嚴重地削減衰退。
本章重點討論戰後國際貨幣制度對美國國內政治經濟的影響,說明美元關鍵貨幣的地位和美國收支赤字提供的流動性,產生了在流動性創造機制的鑄幣稅問題和調整機制的善意忽略問題。
這些制度缺陷在戰後國際貨幣制度,在三個特別的方式影響美國
首先,聯邦政府將政策自主權視為優先考量目標,用債務融資追求政策目標,結果造成預算赤字和聯邦債務成為全球流動性過剩的主要來源。
其次,美國金融產業一直強調信用創造的競爭力,證券化社會不同的資產、高槓桿的借出貨幣,以及逃避政府的監管,這直接導致說明了次貸危機的爆發。
第三,受美元關鍵貨幣地位的影響,美國的製造業領導全球製造的發展,也支持了出口導向的國家和石油輸出組織OPEC全球過剩的儲蓄,隨著跨國公司大量投資海外,美國製造業的工作創造能力嚴重地削減衰退。
The mechanisms that eventually induced both global
liquidity and saving gluts emerged under the Bretton Woods system. Under this
system, the dollar served as the only key currency, and played the important
roles of the reserve, intervention, vehicle, and transaction currencies in
international finance.
The concept of a key currency has a strong
tie with gold. It used to refer to the central currencies, including the pound
sterling, the dollar, franc, and mark, under the gold-exchange standard in
1925-31 (Shinkai 1975: 61). These key currencies maintained their par values
against gold, and other currencies tied themselves to these currencies. The
key currencies played an important bridging role with countries that did not
have enough gold to back up their own currencies directly, enabling these countries
to engage in international trade.
The United States’ holdings of gold provided
the foundation for the dollar’s key currency status in the postwar period.
Between 1913 and 1944, the United States’ share of the world’s publicly owned
gold increased from 27 percent to 60 percent (Hansen 1946: 86). When the
Bretton Woods system was established after World War II, none of the member
countries, with the exception of the United States, had a sufficient amount of
gold to choose the option of selling and buying gold to maintain the par value
of their currencies, and many of them did not even have enough dollars for the
same purpose (Shinkai 1975: 55).
The Bretton Woods agreement gave the dollar
the same role as gold in the postwar international monetary regime. It
introduced a par value system in which currencies were exchanged at equal
value. The values of various member countries’ currencies were measured by gold
or the dollar. In theory, the par values of various currencies were measured by
gold. Only, for the purpose of easy calculation, the Bretton Woods system used
the dollar to reflect a currency’s value against gold via a fixed exchange rate,
with one ounce of gold equaling $35.
The dollar’s role as the key currency is
reflected in both official and private domains. In the official domain, the
dollar has functioned as both the reserve and the intervention currency. The
term “reserve currency” refers to the currency used as foreign exchange
reserves. “Intervention currency” refers to the currency used by central banks
to intervene in foreign exchange markets. The reserve function and the
intervention function of the key currency are two sides of the same coin. The
central banks must hold the key currency as reserve in order to intervene in
the foreign exchange markets when it becomes necessary (Yamamoto 1988: 168).
In the private domain, the dollar has
functioned as both the vehicle and the transaction currency. The term “vehicle
currency” refers to the currency used by private banks in their interbank
foreign exchange transactions. “Transaction currency” refers to the currency
used by private corporations in their foreign trade transactions. Here the key
currency plays the role of the transaction currency not only between the
issuing country and its trading partners, but also among the countries’ exports
and imports that do not involve the issuing country, the United States
(Yamamoto 1988: 168).
The dollar’s dominance in the postwar
international monetary regimes started with its role in the official domain.
Under the Bretton Woods system, all international monetary fund (IMF) member
countries were obligated to maintain the par value of their currencies, and the
market exchange rates between its own currency and other currencies within 1
percent of its par values. When the market exchange rates of a currency went up
or down beyond 1 percent, the central bank of that country had to intervene to
reestablish its value through either gold or the dollar. However, in the
postwar period no country other than the United States had enough gold to
establish convertibility between gold and its currency. As a result, these
countries had to use the dollar as the intervention currency.
The dollar’s official functions as reserve
and intervention currencies helped it become the vehicle currency in foreign
exchange in the private domain. Since the dollar could be used to determine
other currencies’ par values, holding the dollar could significantly reduce a
country’s foreign exchange risks. The dollar’s official functions also reduced
the risks associated with foreign exchange in the private domain. Because of
these benefits, private banks involved in foreign exchange business in various
countries all used the dollar as their vehicle currency in interbank foreign
exchange transactions (Shinkai 1975).
As more private banks used the dollar as their vehicle
currency, private corporations also began to use the dollar as transaction
currency in settling their foreign trade. In the 1950s and 1960s, the dollar
competed intensively with the pound sterling in providing import insurance. The
dollar won this battle because of the size and the low interest rate of US banks’
supply of credit in the acceptance system. Since the United States was the key
currency country, the New York acceptance market was sizable. Because of the
economy of scale of this market, American banks were able to provide credits
to foreign trading companies with interest rates between 0.3 and 3 percent
lower than those provided by the London market. As a result, many foreign
companies began to use the dollar to settle their transactions in international
trade (Inoue 1994).
布列敦森林協議最終造成了全球流動性和儲蓄過剩的出現,在這系統下,美元儲備成為唯一的關鍵貨幣,在國際金融上扮演重要的角色;準備金、干預、調節和轉換匯率。
關鍵貨幣的概念與黃金有強烈關聯,在過去使用集中貨幣包含了英鎊、美元、法郎和馬克在金本位制下1925-31(Shinkai 1975:61)
關鍵貨幣維持與黃金兌換的價值,而其他貨幣緊盯這些貨幣,關鍵貨幣扮演和其他國家的重要橋樑,是否有足夠的黃金支撐他們自己的貨幣,使這些國家參與國際貿易。
美國戰後持有的黃金比列從27%增加到60% ,提供美元關鍵貨幣的基礎(Hansen 1946:86) 。
二次大戰後當BW系統的建立,除了美國之外,許多國家沒有擁有黃金的有效帳戶執行選擇賣和賣的選擇權,來維持國家貨幣的票面價值,有沒有足夠的美元來達成同樣的目的(Shinkai 1975:55) 。
BW同意給予美元像黃金同樣的角色在戰後國際的貨幣制度,介紹了票面價值的系統在相同價值下的匯率交換,個別成員國的貨幣價值是藉由黃金或美元來衡量。
為了容易計算的目的,BW系統使用一盎司黃金等於35美元的固定交換利率。
美元作為關鍵貨幣的角色反應在官方和私部門領域,在公領域,美元作為準備和干預貨幣的功能:準備貨幣的使用外匯交換的準備金,干預貨幣的使用中央銀行調節外國的外匯市場。
中央銀行必須持有關鍵貨幣,為了調節國外的外匯市場,當有需要的時候(Yamamoto 1988:168) 。
在私部門領域,美元的功能是調節和交易貨幣:調節貨幣的使用是私人銀行和銀行間外匯交易,交易貨幣的使用是私人企業他們的國外貿易交易。
IMF會員國有義務維持該國貨幣的面值,一旦有1% 的變動,該國的中央銀行會涉入重建貨幣的價值經由黃金或美元。
然而,戰後除了美國,沒有國家有足夠的黃金去建立可轉換性,在黃金和該國貨幣之間,結果,這些國家必須使用美元作為干預貨幣。
美元的官方做為準備和干預貨幣的功能幫助他成為調節貨幣在私部門領域的外匯交換。既然美元能夠決定其他貨幣的票面價值,持有美元能夠降低國家的外匯風險。
因為這些好處,私人銀行涉入外匯交易的商業在不同的國家,全部都使用美元作為調節貨幣在銀行間的外匯交易(Shinkai 1975) 。
1950和1960年,美元和英鎊在提供進口保險的競爭,因為美國銀行在信用的提供,規模上和低利率的優勢,贏得了戰場。
布列敦森林協議最終造成了全球流動性和儲蓄過剩的出現,在這系統下,美元儲備成為唯一的關鍵貨幣,在國際金融上扮演重要的角色;準備金、干預、調節和轉換匯率。
關鍵貨幣的概念與黃金有強烈關聯,在過去使用集中貨幣包含了英鎊、美元、法郎和馬克在金本位制下1925-31(Shinkai 1975:61)
關鍵貨幣維持與黃金兌換的價值,而其他貨幣緊盯這些貨幣,關鍵貨幣扮演和其他國家的重要橋樑,是否有足夠的黃金支撐他們自己的貨幣,使這些國家參與國際貿易。
美國戰後持有的黃金比列從27%增加到60% ,提供美元關鍵貨幣的基礎(Hansen 1946:86) 。
二次大戰後當BW系統的建立,除了美國之外,許多國家沒有擁有黃金的有效帳戶執行選擇賣和賣的選擇權,來維持國家貨幣的票面價值,有沒有足夠的美元來達成同樣的目的(Shinkai 1975:55) 。
BW同意給予美元像黃金同樣的角色在戰後國際的貨幣制度,介紹了票面價值的系統在相同價值下的匯率交換,個別成員國的貨幣價值是藉由黃金或美元來衡量。
為了容易計算的目的,BW系統使用一盎司黃金等於35美元的固定交換利率。
美元作為關鍵貨幣的角色反應在官方和私部門領域,在公領域,美元作為準備和干預貨幣的功能:準備貨幣的使用外匯交換的準備金,干預貨幣的使用中央銀行調節外國的外匯市場。
中央銀行必須持有關鍵貨幣,為了調節國外的外匯市場,當有需要的時候(Yamamoto 1988:168) 。
在私部門領域,美元的功能是調節和交易貨幣:調節貨幣的使用是私人銀行和銀行間外匯交易,交易貨幣的使用是私人企業他們的國外貿易交易。
IMF會員國有義務維持該國貨幣的面值,一旦有1% 的變動,該國的中央銀行會涉入重建貨幣的價值經由黃金或美元。
然而,戰後除了美國,沒有國家有足夠的黃金去建立可轉換性,在黃金和該國貨幣之間,結果,這些國家必須使用美元作為干預貨幣。
美元的官方做為準備和干預貨幣的功能幫助他成為調節貨幣在私部門領域的外匯交換。既然美元能夠決定其他貨幣的票面價值,持有美元能夠降低國家的外匯風險。
因為這些好處,私人銀行涉入外匯交易的商業在不同的國家,全部都使用美元作為調節貨幣在銀行間的外匯交易(Shinkai 1975) 。
1950和1960年,美元和英鎊在提供進口保險的競爭,因為美國銀行在信用的提供,規模上和低利率的優勢,贏得了戰場。
Since the Bretton Woods system collapsed, the dollar
has maintained its key currency status, sustained partly by its old role of
pricing oil and other commodities and partly by its new role associated with
managing the risks of the foreign exchange rate in the floating system.
Oil is one of the most important commodities
in the world. After the gold window was closed in 1971, the rapid depreciation
of the dollar triggered two oil crises. By 1973 the dollar had fallen to about
one third of its previous value. Under strong pressure to avoid losses, the
OPEC countries launched oil price hikes that tripled the oil price in the first
oil crisis in 1973-4 (Morris 2008: 10). Between January 1977 and April
1978, the US dollar again depreciated rapidly against other major currencies.
In addition, at this time OPEC countries held roughly $70 billion in liquid
reserves and some $80 billion in foreign placement, half of which was kept in
dollar deposits and dollar assets. Because of this, OPEC countries tripled the
price of crude oil in the second oil crisis in 1978-9 (Amuzegar 1978).
Between the two oil crises, OPEC countries
seriously discussed the possibility of replacing the dollar with other
alternatives to price oil. As early as in June 1975, a proposal to switch to
special drawing rights (SDR) was discussed at the OPEC ministers’ summer
meeting in Gabon. In mid-1976, interest in a multicurrency basket as the basis
for oil pricing was revived (Amuzegar 1978).
The dollar survived as the key currency
because the United States successfully negotiated with Saudi Arabia to
continue using the dollar to price oil. The fact that OPEC continued to use the
dollar to price oil provided the dollar with a new base of legitimacy as the
key currency. So long as various countries needed to import oil, holding the
dollar as their foreign reserves would significantly reduce the risks
associated with the fluctuation of foreign exchange rates and thus maintain
energy security. The United States also promised favorable interest rates for
the petrodollars that were recycled back to US Treasury bonds. By doing so, it
obtained the capital necessary for surviving the economic downturn (Spiro
1999).
The dollar’s key currency status was also
sustained by its roles as vehicle and transaction currencies in various newly
created financial instruments. These roles were reflected in three distinctive
areas.
First, managing exchange rate risks demanded
greater supplies of the dollar. The collapse of the Bretton Woods system
shifted the responsibility of managing exchange rate risks from central banks
to private banks, corporations, and individuals. Public authorities were no
longer obligated to intervene in the exchange rate because such interventions
became discretionary. In order to avoid the exchange rate risks, banks that had
exchange business had to rely on capital mobility to fill the gap in its
settlement of payments, using speculative short-term capital to balance their
daily settlement residues. This significantly increased the demand for the
dollar (Eatwell and Taylor 2000).
Second, as a response to the need to manage
exchange risks under the floating exchange rate system, financial instruments
such as currency options and currency swaps experienced major development. In
the past, the oversupply of the dollar had been the major destabilizer in the
international monetary order. Ironically, under the dollar standard the
oversupply of the dollar became the precondition for the operation of various
financial instruments designed to reduce exchange rate risks. As a result,
despite the fact that the dollar became weaker, the need to hedge the weaker
dollar resulted in its greater usage (Kataoka 1992 [1986]).
Third, since the early 1970s, Germany and Japan have
emerged as the major competitors to the United States. Despite the fact that
the Japanese yen and German mark increased their shares in international
reserves, they could not directly exchange with each other without using the
dollar as the vehicle currency. Technically, the exchange rate between yen and
mark could not be calculated against each other; they had to be calculated by
using the yen-dollar rate and mark-dollar rate. As German and Japanese banks
and corporations rapidly expanded their international businesses, they needed
more dollars for the settlements of payments (Kataoka 1993).
美元仍維持關鍵貨幣角色的原因,在於保持石油和原物料仍採美元計價以及能夠處理流動系統中外匯交易風險的問題。
兩次石油危機,1973年美元票面價值跌到只剩1/3,和 1978-9年OPEC石油輸出組織將原油價格提高3倍,1976年OPEC認真考慮取代美元定價的方案,屬意重新使用一籃子貨幣為石油計價的標準,因為美國成功地與沙烏地阿拉伯協商繼續使美元計價,到目前個別國家仍須使用美元進口石油,用美元做準備金能夠降低外匯波動的風險,維持能源安全。
美元關鍵貨幣的地位藉由作為調節貨幣和交易貨幣,在不同創新的金融工具仍使用美元,在三個特別的領域
管理匯率風險,仍需要更多的美元提供,BW系統的失敗轉換了處理匯率風險的責任從中央銀行,變為私人銀行,公司集團到個人,為了避免匯率交易風險,銀行必須改變商業模式仰賴資本的流動性,使用短期投資資本去平衡每日的結算差額,更增加了美元的需求。 (Eatwell and Taylor 2000)
金融工具例如匯率選擇權和貨幣交換經歷重要的發展,過去美元過分供給,成為國際貨幣制度下不穩定的製造者,諷刺地是、在美元本位制下,美元的超額供給變成操作個別金融工具的設計下,降低匯率風險的先決條件,結果造成了美元雖然變弱,因避險需求造成更大程度的使用。 (Kataoka 1992)
自從1970年早期,德國和日本成為美國的主要競爭者,雖然日圓和馬克在國際儲備增加他們的股份比例,但是他們仍然無法彼此兌換沒有使用美元作為調節貨幣,技術上,日圓與馬克也無法彼此計算匯率,必須藉由個別轉換為美元才可以計算,所以德國和日本銀行和公司快速擴張他們的國際貿易,仍需要更多的美元來清算的支付。(Kataoka 1992)
美元仍維持關鍵貨幣角色的原因,在於保持石油和原物料仍採美元計價以及能夠處理流動系統中外匯交易風險的問題。
兩次石油危機,1973年美元票面價值跌到只剩1/3,和 1978-9年OPEC石油輸出組織將原油價格提高3倍,1976年OPEC認真考慮取代美元定價的方案,屬意重新使用一籃子貨幣為石油計價的標準,因為美國成功地與沙烏地阿拉伯協商繼續使美元計價,到目前個別國家仍須使用美元進口石油,用美元做準備金能夠降低外匯波動的風險,維持能源安全。
美元關鍵貨幣的地位藉由作為調節貨幣和交易貨幣,在不同創新的金融工具仍使用美元,在三個特別的領域
管理匯率風險,仍需要更多的美元提供,BW系統的失敗轉換了處理匯率風險的責任從中央銀行,變為私人銀行,公司集團到個人,為了避免匯率交易風險,銀行必須改變商業模式仰賴資本的流動性,使用短期投資資本去平衡每日的結算差額,更增加了美元的需求。 (Eatwell and Taylor 2000)
金融工具例如匯率選擇權和貨幣交換經歷重要的發展,過去美元過分供給,成為國際貨幣制度下不穩定的製造者,諷刺地是、在美元本位制下,美元的超額供給變成操作個別金融工具的設計下,降低匯率風險的先決條件,結果造成了美元雖然變弱,因避險需求造成更大程度的使用。 (Kataoka 1992)
自從1970年早期,德國和日本成為美國的主要競爭者,雖然日圓和馬克在國際儲備增加他們的股份比例,但是他們仍然無法彼此兌換沒有使用美元作為調節貨幣,技術上,日圓與馬克也無法彼此計算匯率,必須藉由個別轉換為美元才可以計算,所以德國和日本銀行和公司快速擴張他們的國際貿易,仍需要更多的美元來清算的支付。(Kataoka 1992)
Under the Bretton Woods system, the United States
served as the major supplier of liquidity for the international economy. It
pledged to maintain the convertibility of the dollar with gold. In exchange,
the United States was exempted from two major obligations: maintenance of its
payments balance, and stabilization of exchange rates between the dollar and
other currencies. These exemptions contained major defects:
they created the problem of seigniorage in the
mechanism of liquidity creation, and the problem of benign neglect in the
mechanism of adjustment.
Seigniorage originally meant “the difference
between the circulating value of a coin and the cost of bullion and minting,
involving a once-for-all gain to the coin’s issuer (the sovereign or
‘seigneur’)” (Cohen 1977: 67). In its contemporary usage, however, seigniorage
refers to “the capacity that a monetary monopoly gives national governments to
augment public spending at will” (Cohen 1998: 39). Issuance of the key currency
in the world provides the issuing country with “structural power” (Strange
1986), or “exorbitant privilege” (d’Estaing, cited in Eichengreen 2011). Since
many other countries need the key currency for reserves, issuing such a reserve
currency can become “an alternative source of revenue for the state, beyond
what government can raise through taxation or borrowing from financial markets”
(Cohen 1998: 39).
The problem of seigniorage was directly
linked to the practice under the Bretton Woods system of relying on US payment
deficits to supply liquidity to the international economy. Since the dollar was
the only key currency for much of the postwar period, it became inevitable that
the United States, as the major supplier of liquidity to the international
economy, would have enduring deficits in its payments. Under the Bretton Woods
system, central banks around the world had to use the dollar to measure the par
value of their own currencies and as their reserve currencies, and to intervene
with the dollar in foreign exchange markets to maintain the parity between the
dollar and their own currencies. Because of these international demands for the
key currency, the total supply of the dollar had to be much greater than the
United States’ own need (Arima 1978).
Robert Triffin points out that the postwar
supply of liquidity relied on the payments imbalance of the United States. The
deterioration of US payments, however, would inevitably affect international
confidence in the dollar. Since the goal of the key currency country in its
monetary policy is different from the goal of the system as a whole, this would
lead sooner or later to either a change in the practice of relying on one
country’s currency as the key currency by creating alternative sources of
liquidity, or the collapse of the Bretton Woods system. His argument on the
instability of relying on a reserve currency gained increasing support with the
US government (Odell 1982: 130-6).
The oversupplied liquidity from the US
payment deficits created a dollar glut as early as the beginning of the 1960s.
Despite the fact that the central bank of the recipient country would use this
capital, these dollars in fact remained in an account with a commercial bank
in New York City in the form of deposits, an account used by the central bank
to intervene in the foreign exchange market to keep its own currency in parity.
As a result, these dollars were used at least twice: first as American
purchasing power in Europe since the United States was the creditor, and then
as domestic purchasing power within the United States. No matter how much
deficit appeared in US payments as a result of supplying liquidity for other
countries, there was no impact on its own domestic purchasing power. When the
movement of capital across national borders became
THE
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REGIME 323
intense, such mechanisms became the major reason for
inflation on a global scale (Rueff 1971: 28-9, 36-41).
In theory, under the Bretton
Woods system US holdings of gold should have functioned as a checking
mechanism against the oversupply of liquidity into the international economy.
If the United States oversupplied liquidity, its payments condition would
deteriorate rapidly. Increasing payment deficits would lead to the loss of
international confidence in the dollar, which in turn would trigger
conversions from dollars to gold by foreign central banks. In reality, however,
such a fear was never a sufficient threat. European countries began to convert
their dollars into gold in the late 1950s.
When the United States decided to close the gold window
in 1971, its gold holdings had declined nearly 60 percent, from $24.4 billion
in 1948 to $10.2 billion (Gavin 2006: 209).
After the dollar standard replaced the Bretton Woods
system in the 1970s, the constraint on the US supply of liquidity no longer
existed. The dollar was no longer backed by gold, and US borrowings from
overseas were no longer backed by domestic savings (Duncan 2003). The checking
mechanism of gold conversion, although not perfect, disappeared completely.
Why did the United States and
the international community not change the practice of relying on one country’s
currency as the key currency after the collapse of the Bretton Woods system?
The reason was that the minority view represented by Charles Kindleberger and
his associates in the debate on the dollar provided legitimacy for the attitude
of benign neglect after the gold window was closed.
The minority view in the debate on the dollar presented
a different interpretation of US payment deficits from that presented by Robert
Triffin: it argued that the payment deficits of the United States did not
represent a disequilibrium because these deficits were offset by the inflows of
capital from foreign countries that attempted to put their monies into liquid
dollar assets. In international finance the United States did not simply supply
liquidity; rather, it provided an intermediation service in not only lending
long-term capital but also providing better opportunities for foreign
short-term capital to make profits. Thus the United States did not have to raise
the interest rate to cool down its overspending. So long as savings in Europe
were high, the free flows of capital would still exceed the real transfer of
goods and services (Despres, Kindleberger, and Salant 1966; Schwartz 2009).
Supported by this minority
view, the problem of benign neglect worsened after the early 1970s. Benign
neglect was a policy of officially doing nothing to address the issue of
current account deficits.
The problem of benign neglect in the
mechanism of adjustment first resulted from the arrangement under the Bretton
Woods system that exempted the United States from the responsibility of
maintaining parities between the dollar and other currencies. According to the
IMF agreement, the United States, by committing itself to buying and selling
gold with a fixed exchange rate with the dollar, the responsibility of
maintaining the value of the dollar against other currencies was in the hands
of other member countries (Iwano 1977: 100; Shimazaki 1983: 225).
In theory, under the Bretton Woods system
the intervention of monetary authorities in the currency market functioned as
an adjustment to the shortage of the dollar in the international settlement of
private banks. When a country’s international payments had deficits, the demand
for the dollar increased. As a result, the dollar became stronger in its
exchange rate with that country’s currency. To fulfill its obligation under the
Bretton Woods agreement, the monetary authority of that country had to
intervene by selling the dollar in an effort to contain the fluctuation of the
exchange rate within a certain range. The dollars used in these interventions
came from either trade surpluses accumulated in the past or exchanges using
the country’s gold reserves. The former represented a process of dynamic
payments balance over time, and the latter represented the ultimate settlement
with gold, since gold-dollar exchanges and public interventions had become an
integral process, and both served to adjust the shortage of the dollar in the
private sector (Kataoka 1993: 61).
In practice, however, payments settlement
through the gold-dollar exchange was not always achieved because the imbalance
in international payments did not always lead to interventions by monetary
authorities. Even after the payments imbalance took place, the equilibrium of
exchange rates could still be maintained by credits from private banks in the
form of short-term capital movement, which functioned to repeatedly delay settlement
of the imbalance in international payments. In this case, the imbalance of payments
did not immediately result in gold-dollar exchanges by the monetary authorities
(Kataoka 1993: 62).
After the gold window closed, the monetary
authorities gave up their responsibility to intervene in the currency market
except on rare occasions. As the need of using gold for international
settlements disappeared, so did the pressure for immediate adjustment. Under
the new system international settlements take the form of balancing out debts
and credits with exchange transactions. When the payments cannot be balanced,
countries would rather delay settlement by relying on international supplies
and acceptance of credits to fill the gap. Under the dollar standard the dollar
has lost its backup by gold, and its usage is completely sustained by its
perceived purchasing power (Kataoka 1993: 63). As a result, partial settlement
with gold under the Bretton Woods system disappeared, the clearance by
introducing short-term borrowing to fill the gap in the current account became
a common practice, and the time horizon for the delay increased substantially
(Andrews 2006: 11; Cohen 2006: 31).
Under the dollar standard, countries rely on
finance strategy instead of adjustment strategy to muddle through payment
deficits. A government has two options to deal with deficits. With the
adjustment option, the government tries to reallocate resources.
It either changes the country’s expenditures by
adopting deflationary monetary and fiscal policies that reduce the quantity of
money available in the economy or by increasing taxation and reducing public
spending in an effort to decrease the aggregated demand, or switches the
country’s expenditure by relying on price changes that alter the allocation of
total spending between tradable and non-tradable goods, aiming at promoting
exports and bringing deficits down (Cohen 1977: 26-7).
With the finance option, the government
avoids reallocation of resources. When payment deficits take place, the
government or the central bank seeks to sell foreign exchange or to intervene
in the financial and exchange markets to induce inflows of short-term capital.
In order to counteract the negative impacts of the change in the country’s net
foreign liquidity on internal purchasing power, they conduct domestic open
market operations in government securities, or adjust private bank reserve
requirements or liquidity ratios. In order to close the gap in payments they
accommodate flows of public and/or private funds and at the same time keep
incomes, prices, existing demand-and-supply schedules of foreign exchange, and
the prevailing exchange rate untouched (Cohen 1977: 26).
The financing option is always more popular
than the adjusting option in domestic politics because it involves no changes
in income and prices, and the effects of adjustment are smaller. Choosing the
financing option, however, requires that the government has access to a
stockpile of internationally acceptable liquid assets. Treasury bills or notes
become useful because US monetary authorities hold a large pool of government
securities for domestic market operations. Since the United States can always
sell dollar- based debts to foreign countries, it has the capacity, unlike any
other country, to generate the flows of capital needed for the financing
option in the adjustment of payments disequilibrium.
Benign neglect has functioned to eliminate
adjustment pressures on the United States that would otherwise force it to
address its payments imbalance. Delaying any adjustment to its rising current
account deficits opened a window for ever-increasing deficits in US payments
that have led to ever-increasing Federal debts, since the United States had to
borrow both internationally and domestically to make up these deficits.
The seigniorage problem in the mechanism of liquidity
creation and the benign neglect problem in the mechanism of adjustment in the
postwar international monetary regimes have significantly affected the
behaviors of domestic actors in the United States.
The seigniorage problem in the postwar international
monetary regimes enabled the US government to maintain a strong preference for
policy autonomy and act freely, insulated from outside pressures in its policy
formulation and implementation (Cohen
OCN^tCDCOOCN^tCDCOOCN^tCDCOOCN^tCDCOOCN^tCDCOOCN^tCDCO
LOLOLOLOLOcflcccDcD^NNNNNcococococooooax^ooooo
T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—*—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—T—C^C^C^C^C\
|
Total
Millitary Cost of War — National Defense — % of GDP
figure
16.1
National Defense and Major War Spending of the US Federal Government, 1950-2008
Sources: National defense spending and GDP: Office of
Management and Budget; Historical Tables: Budget of the US Government, Fiscal
Year 2010; Total military cost of war: Stephen Daggett, Costs of Major US Wars,
Congressional Research Service, July 24, 2008/Value in current dollar. War
costs only include appropriations
enacted
through June 30, 2008.
2006: 32). Such a strong preference for policy autonomy
is reflected in its spending, especially in national defense, tax cuts, and
social spending. Among these three, national defense has received bipartisan
support, while tax cuts have been supported more by Republican administrations
and increasing social spending has been supported more by Democratic
administrations.
Global strategic objectives have been the
top priority in the policy autonomy guarded by the US government. In the
postwar period the United States launched several wars, including the Korean
War, the Vietnam War, two wars in Iraq, and the war in Afghanistan. As Figure
16.1 indicates, spending on wars always substantially increased the weight of defense
spending in GDP (gross domestic product). In war finances the initial estimates
of war costs have invariably fallen short of actual expenditures. The executive
branch has relied heavily on supplementary appropriations to fund military
conflicts, despite frequent clashes with Congress. These appropriations are not
calculated against the total annual budget, and they tend to mask the actual
size of annual budget deficits (Miller 2007). In addition, the US government
has spent significantly on military and economic aid to its allies and its
various military bases overseas. Despite the concern over the negative impact
of overseas military spending on US payment balances during the four
administrations in 1958-73, the US government never withdrew its commitment to
military capacities (Gavin 2004).
O»-CNr0^tL0CDr-^c0c^o»—CNr0^tL0CDr-^c0c^o»—CNr0^tL0CDr-^c0c^o»—CNr0^tL0CDr-^c0
i-sNrsNNNNrsrsrsaaJaacocococococoocDa^^aiaiaiax^c^oooooooQo
c^o^a^c^c^c^c^c^c^c^c^o^a^c^oc^c^c^c^c^c^o^c^c^c^c^c^c^c^c^ooooooooo
|
figure 16.2 Revenue Effects of US
Major Tax Cuts
Source:
Tempalski (2006).
Notes: Values in current dollar. The revenue
effect is based on the two-year average (1970-7) and four-year average
(1978-2006).
#
# Tax cuts have been another major objective for the US
policy autonomy, beginning with the Kennedy Administration and continuing through
much of the Johnson Administration. Later they were supported more by
Republicans, especially under the Reagan and Bush administrations. As Figure
16.2 indicates, tax cuts under these two Republican administrations had
substantial implications for government revenues.
Taxes on dividends, interest, capital gains, estates
and gifts, and corporate profits are considered the lifeblood of the
entrepreneurial class (Morgan 2009: 209). The Republicans’ attitudes toward tax
cuts have been sustained by two versions of supply- side economic theories. The
earlier version perceived labor expansion and technological innovation to be
fixed elements, and argued that tax cuts could boost capital expenditure,
which in turn would promote production capacity. In contrast, the later version
believed that tax cuts as well as technological innovation and the economic
potential of such innovation would outstrip what was possible through the
growth of capital expenditure alone (Morgan 2009: 209-10).
Social spending is the third
policy priority. As Figure 16.3 shows, the rapid increase of social spending
started with the Great Society program under the Johnson Administration in the
1960s. Once social spending became a policy priority, it was difficult to
abandon. Even the Republican administrations after Johnson accepted the
premises set forth in the 1960s, and this policy priority lasted at least until
Reagan came into power. Despite the image of Republicans (represented by
Reagan) as against social spending, however, significant social spending has
not been limited only to the
---- Education, training, employment,
and social services Health
— Medicare — -
Income security ---------------- Social
security
|
figure 16.3 Social Spending of the
US Federal Government, 1950-2008
Source: OMB (2010). Values in
current dollar.
#
# Democratic administrations. Both Richard Nixon and
George W. Bush were known for their spending on social programs. In the
beginning the architects of the Great Society program were interested primarily
in creating opportunities for the poor to participate in the economic
mainstream; over time, however, the Great Society program created an unexpected
expansion of income security programs that allowed welfare-type programs
(Kaplan and Cuciti 1986).
The strong preference of the
US government for policy autonomy is exemplified by the fact that it has often
pursued multiple costly policy objectives simultaneously. As the four cases
below demonstrate, the US government has either made major tax cuts that
reduced revenues while pursuing a war or a major defense program, or
substantially increased social spending during a war. This kind of overspending
has inevitably led to skyrocketing budget deficits and the rapid increase of
Federal debts. Easily accessible capital and the need to fill the gap in
deficits and debts have created a favorable environment for the formation of a
liquidity glut.
The Johnson Administration
not only expanded the war in Vietnam and launched the Great Society program,
but also refused to raise taxes to finance them. Between 1960 and 1965, the US
defense expenditure increased on average by merely 1.6 percent annually, and
the total expenditure of the US government budget increased on average by 5.1
percent annually. After Johnson signed on to both the expansion of the Vietnam
War and the Great Society program, on average defense expenditures grew 18.9
percent annually and nondefense expenditures grew 13.0 percent annually (Mowery
and
Kamplet 1982: 17). During the Johnson years decisions
on new legislation and defense spending were made with no coordination with
budgetary preparation, and defense decisions that had major economic
implications were not communicated to Johnson’s economic advisers (Mowery and
Kamplet 1982). President Johnson attempted to avoid jettisoning his ambitious
Great Society program during a period of mushrooming defense expenditures in
Vietnam. Despite severe obstacles to the pursuit of a guns-and- butter policy,
“Johnson chose to ignore or override as many such obstacles as possible.
Inasmuch as such obstacles were manifested most clearly in the fiscal and
budgetary policy processes, Johnson chose in the later years of his
administration to bypass these policy processes” (Mowery and Kamplet 1982: 16).
This spending led to severe inflation and an overheated economy, which
seriously undermined international confidence in the dollar. This was a major
factor that contributed to the collapse of the Bretton Woods system.
Under the Reagan Administration the major
driver for the Federal budget was defense. For Reagan any retreat from the
established growth target would send the wrong signal to the Soviet Union. Even
in his second term, defense spending averaged $390 billion (in fiscal year 2000
dollars), compared with the Carter average of $264 billion. This level was
exceeded only by the Korean War budgets of the 1952-3 fiscal year and the
Vietnam War budget of the 1968-1969 fiscal year. Moreover, this big increase in
defense expenditure coincided with the biggest tax cuts in the US history
(Morgan 2009: 89). Between the Carter Administration and the first term of the
Reagan Administration, average spending increased from 21.2 percent to 22.9
percent, while tax revenue decreased from 18.8 percent to 17.9 percent. This
resulted in 2.6 percent GDP equivalent Federal debts (Morgan 2009: 86). Reagan
argued that “the deficits we
face are not rooted in
defense spending . . . [or] in tax cuts____________ The
fact is, our deficits
come from the uncontrolled growth of the budget for
domestic spending” (Morgan 2009: 76). He made great efforts to cut social
spending, reducing the total social spending against GDP from 13.7 percent to
12 percent during his two terms. Due to the resistance of the Congress,
however, the effects of these efforts were not as strong as he would have
liked. The adoption of Reaganomics by the US government in the 1980s led to
mounting Federal debts.
Under the Bush Administration the funding of
foreign military operations in Iraq and Afghanistan through emergency
appreciation became a regular practice. It has been estimated that between
fiscal years 2002 and 2005, supplementary spending averaged $120 billion a
year, in contrast to only $14 billion between fiscal years 1975 and 2001
(Morgan 2009: 211). “Reversing ‘tax and spend’ liberalism had been a Republican
goal since the New Deal. In the Bush era, a GOP president and Congress
cooperated to deliver the first half of this mission but found partisan cause
to expand domestic spending at the very moment that they also reversed
post-Cold War defense retrenchment” (Morgan 2009: 231). What distinguished Bush
from Reagan was his self-identity as a “compassionate conservative” on issues
related to social spending, despite the fact that Bush shared Reagan’s
free-market ethos, low-taxes doctrine, and belief in less government
involvement in the economy, and that many of his social programs, such as the
No
330 BAI GAO
Child Left Behind Act, prescription drug entitlement,
and the failed Social Security reform still aimed to enhance individual choice
or facilitate individual capacity to contract with private sector institutions
(Morgan 2009: 211). The pursuit of policy autonomy in multiple policy domains
substantially increased budget deficits and payment deficits and resulted in
skyrocketing Federal debts.
Although the Obama Administration did reduce the scale
of US military involvement in Iraq, it substantially increased the number of
ground troops in Afghanistan. As a result, total war expenditures of the US
government in the 2010 and 2011 fiscal years remained at $171 billion, slightly
higher than the 2007 fiscal-year level and second only to 2008’s figure of
$185 billion, the peak level since September 11, 2001 (CBO 2010: 3). Meanwhile,
Obama adopted the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009. According to
an estimate by the Congressional Budget Office (CBO), this package would lead
to a total of $787 billion budget deficits for the US government in 2009-19
(CBO 2009). In addition, the Obama Administration extended the tax cuts
launched by the Bush Administration for two more years. The $858 billion
package signed in 2010 prevented taxes from rising on January 1, 2011, for
virtually every American household. Of course, this $858 billion not only
represents tax cuts; it also guarantees unemployed workers in hard-hit states
up to 99 weeks of jobless benefits until the end of 2011, and it created major
new incentives for business and consumer spending in 2011, including a 2
percentage point reduction in the Social Security payroll tax that would allow
workers to keep as much as $2,136 (Montgomery, Murray, and Branigin ).
The seigniorage problem and the benign neglect problem contributed
to two developments that played crucial roles in the global financial crisis:
the development of international financial markets that helped the formation
of the global glut of liquidity, and the development of mortgage-backed
securities that directly triggered the subprime loan crisis in the United
States. One of these international financial markets was the Eurodollar market,
which refers to European markets where various dollar-based assets are traded
outside of the United States. Its competition with the New York financial
market became the driving force behind the deregulation efforts; the need of
private corporations and private banks to manage their exchange rate risks led
to the inventions of various financial instruments. One of these instruments,
mortgage- backed securities (MBSs), was developed as a response of the Johnson
Administration to the seigniorage problem in the 1960s. Its growth was greatly
accelerated by the benign neglect problem in the 1970s and eventually led to
the outbreak of the subprime loan crisis in 2007.
The oversupply of liquidity by the United
States in the 1950s was a direct factor in the rise of Eurodollar markets. US
spending on overseas military bases, US military and development aid to its
allies, and its permission to allow its allies to export to the US market while
keeping their domestic markets closed to US products led to the accumulation of
dollars in Western Europe (Gavin 2006; Helleiner 1994). The dollar glut
resulted in two separate developments: one was the rapid expansion of the
Eurodollar market, and the other was the conversion of dollars into gold by
European central banks.
Since central banks in European countries
needed to find a market for these dollars to make profits, Eurodollar markets
emerged and quickly became a favorable way to absorb the dollar glut. Since a
substantial amount of dollars owned by European governments became deposits in
Eurodollar markets, this served to reduce the pressure on the conversion of
gold. Without the Eurodollar market, the US government would have been forced
to close the gold window much earlier (Kawamoto 1993: 182).
Nevertheless, the rise of Eurodollar markets
created competition pressures for the US banking industry. Throughout the
1950s, New York was virtually the only open capital market for foreign
securities, sustained by the dollar’s key currency status and New York’s status
as the center of the international financial market. The economy of scale
enabled American financial institutions to compete with low interest rates and
diversified products to lend money (Einzig 1972: 36). After the Eurodollar
market came into being, it became a supplementary market or an escape channel
for American banks, which began to face increasing government restrictions on
the outflows of capital from the United States in the 1960s (Helleiner 1994).
The collapse of the Bretton Woods system and
the first oil crisis in the early 1970s started a new era in which the
expansion of offshore finance fully blossomed and created strong dynamics for
deregulation. “Even the ability of central banks to regulate the supply of
money and credit was undermined by commercial banks’ borrowing and lending
offshore. This process accelerated after the shock of 1973-74. Within ten
years, national authorities were forced to scrap long-established interest rate
ceilings, lending limits, portfolio restrictions, reserve and liquidity
requirements, and other regulatory paraphernalia . . . the only instrument of
monetary policy available to them was buying and selling securities to
influence short-term interest rates” (Eatwell and Taylor 2000: 37-8).
The pressure for deregulation also came from
private corporations and private banks. After advanced industrialized countries
shifted to the floating exchange rate system, there emerged an overwhelming
need to hedge against the huge costs that fluctuating exchange rates imposed on
private corporations. In order to reduce such risks, those corporations that
traded in foreign markets were forced to diversify their portfolios, changing
the mix of currencies and financial assets, both at present and in the future,
in line with the constantly changing perception of foreign exchange risks. They
demanded the creation of new financial instruments that required the removal of
regulatory barriers. At the same time, private banks regarded the fluctuation
of exchange rates as a great opportunity to make profits. They too demanded
deregulation in order to obtain more freedom to maneuver in the market. Both of
these political currents, together with other domestic factors, led to the
spread of deregulation (Eatwell and Taylor 2000: 2-3).
The need to manage various
risks associated with the floating exchange rates led to the development of new
financial instruments. Commercial papers are a good example. In the 1970s the
government still maintained interest rate ceilings on bank deposits, and the
market rates in the context of inflation had risen substantially above the bank
rates. Under these circumstances, the money-market mutual fund was developed in
1974, offering better rates for investors than bank deposits, and thus
developing rapidly from this point on. Money-market mutual funds later became
the number one investors in commercial papers, and commercial papers became the
number one holdings of money- market mutual funds (IMF Institute). Because of
this, individual consumers no longer kept their cash in their bank savings
account, and corporations began to get funding by issuing commercial papers.
Both trends served to weaken the banking industry and forced banks into either
more service-oriented products, or more risky lending (Mizruchi 2010).
Mortgage-backed securities
developed as a result of the US government’s response to the challenge created
by the seigniorage problem. In the 1960s the Johnson Administration expanded US
involvement in the Vietnam War and also launched the Great Society program.
Nevertheless, it was reluctant to increase taxes. Since many Great Society
programs such as Medicaid, Medicare, and others had already created substantial
budget deficits and the savings and loan industry was not able to finance the
ambitious goals for housing established by the government, the Johnson
Administration reorganized the Federal National Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae)
as a quasi-private organization, created the Federal Home Loan Mortgage
Corporation (Freddie Mac) to compete with Fannie Mae, and relied on the
Government National Mortgage Association (Ginnie Mae) to issue those mortgages
against the risks of default. At the same time, the Federal government did not
want to ultimately hold the mortgages by itself since this could seriously
constrain the amount of mortgages it could originate. As an alternative, it
decided to use its own capital to fund the mortgages and then sell these
mortgages to investors as bonds (Quinn, cited in Fligstein and Goldstein 2010).
Since benign neglect became the US policy toward its
current account imbalance, the government prefers financing over adjusting
because adjusting involves either a reduction of public spending or the
increase of taxation, while financing brings few adverse effects, at least in
the short term. As the social safety net weakens and inequality continues to
increase, voters in the United States have become increasingly impatient. Under
such circumstances,
politicians
love to have banks expand housing credit, for credit achieves many goals at the
same time. It pushes up house prices, making households feel wealthier, and
allows them to finance more consumption. It creates more profits and jobs in
the
financial sector as well as in real estate brokerage
and housing construction__________ Easy
credit has
large, positive immediate, and widely distributed benefits, whereas the costs
all lie in the future. (Rajan 2010: 31)
THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY REGIME 333
The high unemployment rate in the aftermath of the 2008
global financial crisis revealed a major problem, created by the seigniorage
problem in the US economy, which had been hidden for decades: the negative
impact of the dollar’s key currency status and the United States’ role as the
major supplier of liquidity on the American manufacturing industry. This
provides a new context for the old debate on the US manufacturing industry.
When the economic well-being of the United States as a whole becomes the issue,
the focus is on whether the manufacturing industry can create jobs instead of
whether multinational corporations can make more profits by shifting their
production overseas.
Analyzing the US manufacturing industry from
the angle of job-creation capacity, the impact of the international monetary
regime via domestic political economy immediately emerges. The seigniorage
problem since the 1950s provided dynamics for both the financialization of the
economy and the globalization of production: the two driving forces behind the
decline of the US manufacturing industry. The causal mechanism in this process
is the enduring outflows of capital in the form of foreign direct investment
(FDI) from the United States since the 1950s.
Most analyses of the process of
financialization usually start with the 1970s. However, the very principle that
has driven financialization, efficiency in resource allocation, began to affect
US corporations as early as the 1950s. As a result of the diversification of
American industry by the end of World War II, the institutionalization of
multidivisional structure in US corporations, and the changes in the government
antitrust policy that discouraged intra-industry mergers but left the door open
for diversified mergers in different industries, the financial conception of
control emerged as a significant trend among American corporations. The central
offices of large corporations began to treat their product lines and
subdivisions as a portfolio and use the financial criteria to evaluate their
performances. When products or subdivisions did not meet expectations, they
would be divested and new ones purchased (Fligstein 1990: 229).
The adoption of the efficiency principle in
resource allocation soon led to outflows of FDIs from the United States. The US
economy experienced a recession in 1957. This reduced domestic investment
opportunities. In late 1958 Western European countries began to return to
currency conversions. This took away a major barrier that had prevented
American corporations from investing in Western Europe, and it became easy for
them to send back profits from the host countries. At the time, European countries
still maintained high levels of tariffs against American exports. Thus,
building factories there to serve local markets was considered an effective way
to get around protectionism (Block 1977). Meanwhile, the strategic concern of
US multinational corporations over rising European and Japanese competitiveness
became the driving force for the outflows of FDI because American corporations
attempted to beat their
potential
competitors in their home markets before they became too strong (Vernon 1971).
By the late 1950s the oversupply of
liquidity through payment deficits associated with US overseas military bases
had created the dollar glut. Between the late 1950s and the early 1970s, many
people believed that the dollar had been overvalued and the payment deficits of
the United States would sooner or later lead to a major depreciation of the dollar.
This became the driving force behind the outflows of capital for two reasons.
First, the overvalued dollars gave US corporations more purchasing power in
overseas markets and made their acquisitions in foreign countries cheaper.
Second, the enduring prospect of the dollar’s depreciation made international
investments in countries whose currencies were expected to appreciate more
attractive, and domestic investments in the United States more costly.
As discussed earlier, the dollar experienced
two rapid depreciations in the 1970s; each of them induced an oil crisis as
OPEC countries tried to prevent losses from their exports of oil. These radical
changes further pushed capital out of the United States. The decreasing value
of the dollar made corporate assets held domestically worth less, while those
held internationally were worth more, especially in countries whose currencies
were appreciating. At the same time, the drastically increased energy costs
became a heavy burden on domestic production. This hyperinflation created a
hostile environment for the US manufacturing industry’s domestic production.
Since the beginning of the 1980s, the policy
environment in the United States favored the finance industry but disfavored
the manufacturing industry. Paul Volcker’s radical treatment of inflation with
a high interest rate and Donald Regan’s strong dollar policy created great
pressures on the US manufacturing industry from two fronts. The high interest
rates substantially increased the burden on domestic capital and reduced the
incentives of US corporations in investments. Meanwhile, the high interest
rates attracted massive inflows of foreign capital to the US market. That
increased the demand for the dollar and appreciated its value. The strong
dollar did temporarily reduce the outflows of capital. Nevertheless, the rising
value of the dollar weakened the competitiveness of exports from the US
manufacturing industry in international markets. That led to the rapid
deterioration of the current account. After the Plaza Accord in 1985, the
current account deficits did come down; however, the prospect of the
depreciating value of the dollar further pushed US corporations to invest
overseas (Daniel Gros, cited in Schwartz 2009: 129). In the 1980s the theory of
value chain production based on the principle of efficiency in resource
allocation became a dominant corporate strategy in the United States. Its
application inevitably led to the widely spread practice of outsourcing,
further intensifying outflows of capital.
The practice of investing overseas for
higher profitability became widely institutionalized in the US manufacturing
industry. In the heyday of managerial capitalism, corporate ownership in the
United States was dispersed to broaden the base of shareholders. Financially
independent corporations run by professional managers evolved into social
institutions, and provided increased wages and social policies around equal
employment opportunities, safe products, and environmental protection (Davis
2009: 63).
A
group of progressive corporate elites was able to provide collective solutions
to economic and social problems (Mizruchi 2010). Nevertheless, as the financial
conception of control began to take hold, American corporations were under
constant pressure to sustain their profitability, because the structure of US
financial markets directly links corporations’ access to capital and ability to
prevent takeover to their current profitability (Hall and Soskice 2001). At
the same time, increasing financial investments by nonfi- nancial corporations
crowded out real investment by directing capital from the manufacturing
industry to financial investments; these financial investments could also
decrease the funds available for investment capital (Orhangazi 2008).
The
postwar international monetary regimes that relied on the dollar as the key currency
and the United States as the major supplier of liquidity have exerted profound
impacts on the American political economy. These impacts are reflected in two
major legacies. One is described well by Leslie Gelb:
Most nations today beat their
foreign policy drums largely to economic rhythms, but less so the United
States. Most nations define their interests largely in economic terms and deal
mostly in economic power, but less so the United States. Most nations have
adjusted their national security strategies to focus on economic security, but
less so the United States. Washington still principally thinks of its security
in traditional military terms and responds to threats with military means.
(Gelb 2010)
The other can be stated as the following: most nations
that have accumulated significant amounts of savings, excluding those that
depend on exporting natural resources, build their economies on the
manufacturing industry, but less so the United States. This country tends to
see all economic issues in financial terms, deal with all economic problems
with financial means, and regard credit creation as its one-fits-all solution.
After the 2008 global financial crisis,
however, the results of practicing seigniorage and benign neglect began to
directly threaten the dollar’s key currency status. According to forecasts by
the CBO, by 2020 the cumulated debts of the United States could reach $9.5
trillion, equivalent to 90 percent of the country’s total GDP. Given that the
aging population will drive a sharp increase in health-care costs and Federal
interest expenses will rise exponentially, the official debt could hit 110
percent of GDP by 2025 and 180 percent by 2035 (Altman and Haass 2010). This
has profound implications for the US economy.
If international financial markets begin to
punish the United States for overspending, the dollar will collapse, resulting
in severe damage to the US economy. Many countries have begun to sign bilateral
agreements to use their own currencies to settle their bilateral trade. This
will significantly reduce the dollar’s use and, consequently, its international
demand. The Jasmine Revolution that started in Tunisia and Egypt in 2011 has
added some new uncertainties for the United States, given that the critical
role played by the dollar to oil price is the foundation of the dollar
standard.
As the prospects of future international
monetary regimes have changed, signs of US domestic departures from its past
legacies have appeared. Cutting government spending has become a major policy
agenda in American politics. The strong political opposition to government
spending led by the Tea Party movement resulted in major losses for the
Democrats in the 2010 mid-term election. As the 2012 presidential election
approaches, both Republicans and Democrats have used the 2012 budget as a major
testing battle. Opposing President Obama’s cut-and-invest approach,
Representative Ryan Paul of Wisconsin unveiled his party’s plan in April 2011,
which aimed to reduce the budget deficit by $5.8 trillion over the next decade.
President Obama countered with his own plan of cutting the deficit by $4
trillion over the next 12 years, relying partly on tax increases and partly on
spending cuts. Each party has begun to take the position of protecting its top
priority, no longer trying to pursue multiple policy objectives simultaneously.
Among the three main policy domains that used to demonstrate strong US
preference for policy autonomy, Republicans now emphasize tax cuts while
Democrats try to protect social spending, especially Medicare and Medicaid.
Neither party treats national defense as its first priority, and both have
agreed to cut $1 trillion in defense spending in the next decade.
In other domains, however, the prospects remain
unclear. Whether the United States can develop new ways to promote economic
growth without overdependence on credit creation, and whether the country can
rebuild or redevelop the manufacturing industry for the purpose of job creation
will be major issues faced by the United States in the years ahead. One thing
is clear, however: we have entered a new era in which the formation of the
future international monetary regime and US domestic political economy will
mutually shape each other.
結論
戰後國際貨幣制度仰賴美元作為關鍵貨幣以及在美國的政治經濟發展下美國成為流動性的重要供應者應用產生極大的影響。
美國傾向用金融形式看所有經濟的議題,因為在海外政策、定義利率、經濟力量和權力、安全策略上的得天獨厚的條件,處理所有經濟問題,使用金融工具,以及將金融創新視為一套規格適用所有解決問題。
然而債務達9.5兆,佔美國GDP的90%,人口老化造成的醫療照護費用的急遽成長,2035年官方的債務將達GDP的180%,對美國經濟造成深遠的影響。
如果國際金融市場開始懲罰美國的過度消費,美元將會衰退,造成美國經濟嚴重的影響,許多國家開始簽署雙邊協議,使用自己的貨幣處理雙方的貿易,將大量地降低美元的使用和它的國際需求。
2011年北非的茉莉花革命,更增添了美元本位制的基礎下石油的價格,造成美國關鍵角色的不確定性。
在國內,削減政府的花費成為各政黨的政策主要目標,以美國優先的政策自主權、共和黨強調減稅保障社會開支特別是醫療和照護補助、兩黨都同意在未來十年削減一兆防禦的花費。
美國是否能夠發展新的方式不需過分依賴信用的創造來提升經濟成長,重新建立發展製造工業創造工作機會,是未來幾年美國主要的議題。
我們進入一個新的紀元,面對未來國際貨幣制度的形成和美國國內政治經濟的相互形成。
結論
戰後國際貨幣制度仰賴美元作為關鍵貨幣以及在美國的政治經濟發展下美國成為流動性的重要供應者應用產生極大的影響。
美國傾向用金融形式看所有經濟的議題,因為在海外政策、定義利率、經濟力量和權力、安全策略上的得天獨厚的條件,處理所有經濟問題,使用金融工具,以及將金融創新視為一套規格適用所有解決問題。
然而債務達9.5兆,佔美國GDP的90%,人口老化造成的醫療照護費用的急遽成長,2035年官方的債務將達GDP的180%,對美國經濟造成深遠的影響。
如果國際金融市場開始懲罰美國的過度消費,美元將會衰退,造成美國經濟嚴重的影響,許多國家開始簽署雙邊協議,使用自己的貨幣處理雙方的貿易,將大量地降低美元的使用和它的國際需求。
2011年北非的茉莉花革命,更增添了美元本位制的基礎下石油的價格,造成美國關鍵角色的不確定性。
在國內,削減政府的花費成為各政黨的政策主要目標,以美國優先的政策自主權、共和黨強調減稅保障社會開支特別是醫療和照護補助、兩黨都同意在未來十年削減一兆防禦的花費。
美國是否能夠發展新的方式不需過分依賴信用的創造來提升經濟成長,重新建立發展製造工業創造工作機會,是未來幾年美國主要的議題。
我們進入一個新的紀元,面對未來國際貨幣制度的形成和美國國內政治經濟的相互形成。
沒有留言:
張貼留言