The
argument that corporate action is embedded in social networks has moved from
critique to conventional wisdom in organization theory in just over a decade
(Granovetter 1985). Organizational scholars have come to pay explicit attention
to the causes and consequences of the various ties linking corporations, such
as the interlocks created when corporations share directors. Moreover,
conceiving of corporations as nodes in networks allows researchers to build on
the well-developed concepts and methods of network analysis to uncover
unexpected regularities. Several studies find that a corporation’s interlock
network centrality (i.e. the number of other firms with which it shares board
members) has a systematic influence on corporate decisions. Central firms are more
likely than peripheral firms to adopt takeover defenses, to make acquisitions
and divestitures, to be involved with political policy organizations and to be
imitated when they adopt golden parachutes and switch stock markets. Centrality
is not simply a proxy for other omitted variables: although correlated with
size, it has little relation to corporate performance and at most a modest
relation to alternative measures of ‘prestige’, and its effects persist when
measures of size and performance are controlled for (see Davis, Yoo, and Baker
2003 for a review). And centrality proves quite stable over time, both during
the 1960s and the 1980s and 1990s: among large US firms, centrality in 1982 was
correlated 0.75 with centrality in 1994 (compared to a 0.85 correlation for
sales during these years).
Centrality
is thus both causally important and stable over time. Why should this be the
case? The answer depends on what it is one thinks board members are for. A central
board is composed of directors who sit on many other boards. The traditional
managerialist view sees directors as ‘ornaments on the corporate Christmas
tree’—decorative objects chosen by the CEO to burnish the firm’s image for the
outside world (particularly the financial markets that evaluate them) while
interfering as little as possible in the operations of the corporation.
Directors who serve on many outside boards—particularly
boards
of prestigious firms—make better ornaments. In contrast, agency theorists see
director centrality as a form of validation by the market for corporate
directors, which rewards effective agents of shareholders with multiple board
seats (Shivdasani 1993). A board’s centrality is a proxy for its quality as a
monitor; thus, the stock market responds differently to the same corporate
actions according to who is on the board, indicating that the market ‘trusts’
some boards more than others (Brickley et al. 1995). But according to the first
view, centrality should have little systematic influence on corporate action,
while the second view implies that centrality should have a positive influence
on corporate performance. Neither of these implications is true: centrality has
a systematic influence on corporate decisionmaking but not on performance.
We argue
that the construct of board status provides a means to integrate research on
the causes and consequences of centrality. A producer’s status in the market is
the perceived quality of its products compared to those of its competitors
(Podolny 1993: 830). What boards ‘produce’ is governance for the shareholders
that elect them and for other constituencies of the corporation. Thus
status—as an attribute of boards—is distinct from the reputation of the
corporation as a whole. Status is particularly important in cases where more
direct evidence of quality is missing. The quality of governance is largely
unobservable, and the actual quality of any individual director is almost
completely opaque from an outsider’s perspective. In the absence of direct
measures, shareholders and others have to rely on imperfect indicators of
quality—such as what other boards directors serve on. Board centrality, as an
indicator of status, can thereby insulate a corporation from shareholder
oversight. Once in place, centrality will expose a firm both to a greater volume
of information about governance at other firms and to more extensive normative
pressures from other boards (Useem 1984), thereby influencing its practices.
This
paper empirically unpacks interlock centrality by examining a panel of the
several hundred largest US firms observed in four-year intervals from 1982 to
1994. We analyze the factors that contribute to centrality over time by
examining the features of firms that prompt them to appoint central directors.
Our results suggest that interlock network centrality is self-reproducing:
independent of performance, size, and corporate reputation, central boards are
better able to attract central directors and CEOs of major corporations, leading
to a relatively enduring status order among corporations (White 1981).
Moreover, while firms that out-perform their industry are somewhat better able
to recruit CEOs and central directors, there is no evidence that boards
composed of these individuals enhance subsequent performance. In other words,
board composition appears to be an effect of performance, not a cause. We
conclude with a discussion of the plausibility of proposed reforms in corporate
governance in light of our findings.
A recent
review defined corporate governance as ‘the ways in which suppliers of finance
to corporations assure themselves of getting a return on their investment’
(Shleifer and Vishny 1997: 737). Theory in the ‘law and economics’ tradition
provides a set of tools for analyzing national systems of corporate governance
in financial terms. In an economy where large corporations are typically owned
by dispersed shareholders with only nominal control over the corporation’s
managers, as in the United States, the basic problem of corporate governance is
to establish arm’s length institutions that secure managerial devotion to
increasing shareholder value. The American system is a matrix of such
institutions that includes accounting rules, securities regulations, corporate
law, the takeover market, and various formal and informal structures (such as
compensation systems) adopted by corporations to promote accountability and
align managerial and shareholder interests. At the center of this matrix is a
shareholder-elected board of directors.
According
to theory in law and economics, the institutions of governance mesh to create
an environment that rewards managers who maximize share price and punishes
those who do not. Both those who own and those who manage have an interest in
maintaining these institutions: investors will not part with their money
without reason to believe that they will get a return, and managers will not be
able to raise capital if they cannot give credible accounts for how they will
use it profitably (Easterbrook and Fischel 1991). Thus, those who run
corporations spontaneously conform to best governance practices to demonstrate
their fitness to the financial markets. ‘The corporation and its securities
are products in financial markets to as great an extent as the sewing machines
or other things the firm makes. Just as the founders of a firm have incentives
to make the kinds of sewing machines people want to buy, they have incentives
to create the kind of firm, governance structure, and securities the customers
in capital markets want’ (Easterbrook and Fischel 1991: 4-5). By hypothesis, an
invisible hand guides corporate practice to serve shareholder interests, from
how to pay executives to who serves on the board.
A body
of recent organizational research undermines this optimistic portrayal of a
self-help corporate world. The rise of activist shareholders promulgating
standards of corporate governance at odds with prevailing practice—and their
vehement opposition by corporate executives—calls into question the imagery of
an invisible hand. Experienced directors of large corporations are almost
unanimous in their opposition to reforms pushed by some of the largest
institutional owners, including separating the positions of CEO and Chairman of
the Board, allowing shareholders to vote on executive compensation, and having
shareholder representatives serve on the board (Neiva 1996). Because boards
generally have the final word under the law, the proposed reforms have experienced
little success. Either the large
shareholders
do not grasp their own interests, or boards are not interested in pursuing
them.
A more
fundamental challenge comes from research finding that conformity to best
practices may be more symbolic than substantive, yet still achieve the ends of
maximizing share price. In a series of papers examining the adoption of
executive compensation plans, Westphal and Zajac (1998) elaborated a
neoinstitutionalist perspective on governance that construes at least some
structures as forms of impression management decoupled from actual practice.
In part as a reaction to shareholder pressures, many large corporations adopted
long-term incentive plans purported to align the interests of executives with
those of shareholders. Yet a surprisingly large number of them announced the
plans without ever actually implementing them—presumably as a form of
shareholder impression management (Westphal and Zajac 1994). Moreover, firms
experienced a significant spike in share price when they announced the plans,
whether or not they ever followed through in implementing them (Westphal and
Zajac 1998). Giving the appearance of conformity to the reigning ‘shareholder
value’ model was sufficient to impress the stock market, even in the absence of
genuine conformity. Share price increases were substantially larger when the
announcement of the plan was accompanied by a rationale emphasizing shareholder
value than when the identical plan was justified using a human resource
explanation (Westphal and Zajac 1998). These findings suggest that ‘cosmetic’
governance reform and appropriate rhetorical spin can be used effectively to
manage the demands of investors. Thus, while activists expect governance
reforms to enhance corporate performance, it appears that governance reforms
are themselves rhetorical performances, intended to persuade activists and
other players in the financial markets of the corporation’s fitness for
investment. Creating ‘the kind of firm, governance structure, and securities
the customers in capital markets want’ involves marketing through rhetoric,
from the letter to the shareholders in the annual report, to how diversified
the corporation portrays its operations on the income statement, to the choice
of directors.
But
choice of directors is distinguished from structural reforms in two ways.
First, director choice entails what Aristotle called ethical appeals, which are
rooted in the character of the individual, rather than appeals to reason, as in
the case of structural reforms (McCloskey 1985: 121-2). Judgments about
directors are judgments about character and ability, not about the validity of
an argument (e.g. claiming a link between a form of compensation and
shareholder interests). Boards are given great discretion under the law because
it is assumed that well-chosen directors—being persons of good character—will
do the right thing without being required to follow a set of detailed
guidelines (which is infeasible in any event). Second, virtually every other
structural reform is ultimately under the control of the board. Board
composition is the master choice from which other reforms spring, and is
therefore the most fundamental decision that shareholders make about
governance. Unlike cosmetic structural changes, such as adopting a new
incentive plan, boards cannot be decoupled from the process of governance.
The
problem for those evaluating corporate boards is that the mysteries of
corporate governance occur behind closed doors, and thus determining the
quality of a given board or director from the outside is quite problematic. The
legal requirements for board composition and structure are minimal, and boards
composed of different individuals organize themselves differently to do what
they do, for better or worse. As Pettigrew and McNulty (1998: 250) put it, ‘the
closer one gets to board process and dynamics, the more real becomes the
generalization that all boards are different’. A profusion of academic
research on boards in recent years provides little guidance on best practices:
even the most basic proposed reforms, such as staffing the board with a
majority of ‘independent’ outsiders, show little relation to subsequent
performance. There is thus no template for outsiders seeking to evaluate a
board’s quality. Director candidates are virtually never made available to
shareholders for the interviews that job candidates endure or the debates and
press scrutiny expected of political candidates. Corporations are obliged to
report certain information when directors are put up for election, but the
requirements are scant. Shareholders and others are therefore left to assess
director qualifications based on the thumbnail sketches included in proxy
statements: the director’s age, primary occupation, share ownership—and the
other boards he or she serves on. These director characteristics can then serve
as proxies (so to speak) for vigilance, dependability, integrity, and
intelligence in folk theories about the qualities of good directors.
The
concepts of signaling and status provide a useful way to parse the issues of
board quality. A signal is an indicator of quality that is under some degree of
control by a producer and whose cost goes down as the producer’s quality goes
up. An indicator that is effortlessly displayed by high-quality producers but
extremely costly for low-quality producers to acquire (e.g. some types of
health care certification) is a useful signal. Status is ‘the perceived quality
of (a) producer’s products in relation to the perceived quality of that
producer’s competitors’ products’ (Podolny 1993: 830). Producers can be ranked
into a relatively enduring status hierarchy. Status comes in part from
connections to other producers: ties to higher status producers help elevate
one’s own status, while ties to low-status producers can compromise it (Podolny
1993). By the same token, we suggest that a board’s status—the perceptions of
quality held by the ‘buyers’ of the board’s ‘products’—is shaped by the number
and perceived quality of the other boards that directors serve on. That is, the
backgrounds of directors and the array of interlocks that they create act as
signals in the ‘market’ for corporate governance.1
Given
little other information to go on, outsiders appear to be swayed by director
connections. For new firms, the addition of a prominent director can serve as a
seal of approval to address the concerns of dubious investors.
Biotech
firm ImClone gained credibility with investors through the appointment of
renowned cancer specialist Dr John Mendelsohn to its board. ImClone’s CEO later
pleaded guilty to insider trading charges in 2002, having dumped much of his
ownership stake ahead of the market after learning that the firm’s only drug
would not even be reviewed by the Food and Drug Administration (FDA).
Large
firms can also benefit from prestige board appointments: Time Warner
experienced a 5% stock price increase when it announced the appointments of the
CEOs of Hilton Hotels and UAL to its board (‘The rush to quality on corporate
boards’, Business
Week,
March 1997). Part of this effect is signaling: the ability to attract and
retain prestigious directors indicates a high-quality board, while low-quality
boards hold no appeal for such individuals. (Dissertation committees follow a
similar dynamic: doctoral students may seek to signal their quality by inviting
prestigious faculty to serve on their committees, but the faculty do not have
to accept.)
Yet there is good reason to
be skeptical that prestigious boards enhance corporate performance. The
counter-examples are legion, as some of the best-known corporate meltdowns
occurred on the watch of highly prestigious boards. Morrison Knudsen’s board
counted among its members the most successful mutual fund manager in history, a
former National Security Advisor, a former Reagan administration official and
judge, a former baseball commissioner, and other equally accomplished
individuals, as it careened toward financial ruin in 1995. The boards of
General Motors and American Express were accused of serious laxity during the
periods before each fired their chief executives, despite being staffed with
several major CEOs and other prominent directors. Money center commercial bank
boards were packed with the CEOs of the largest corporations in America during
the 1980s, even as the banks made disastrous loans that led some (such as
Citicorp) to the brink of insolvency (Davis and Mizruchi 1999). Systematic
research on the link between interlocks and overall corporate performance is
agnostic at best (see Mizruchi 1996 for a review). From the shareholders’
perspective, board status evidently does not merit much potency as a signal.
Yet evidence for the effects of interlocks on corporate decisionmaking—if not
performance—is compelling. Construing a corporation’s portfolio of interlocks
in terms of status connects our discussion of governance with the literature on
the network created by interlocking boards of directors. We now turn to a brief
examination of this network.
The
insight that economic action is shaped by the social structures in which it is
embedded helped usher in the widespread use of network methods in
organizational research (Granovetter 1985). The core of this approach is the
notion that organizations can be conceived as actors (nodes) connected to other
actors through alliances, shared directors, and so on (ties), and that the
resulting social structure could be analyzed as a network. Networks can be
dense or sparse, centralized or Balkanized, with ties being strong or weak. Networks
channel information flow, and thus the structure of a network is consequential:
just as viruses spread faster in urban areas than rural ones, information flows
more quickly in densely connected networks than sparse ones. Given that
organizations are conceived as nodes in networks, an interorganizational
network could be analyzed using well-developed theory in the literatures on
anthropology, small groups, and diffusion of innovation, as well as
sophisticated methodological tools. Notions of ‘status’, ‘opinion leadership’,
‘contagion’, and so on could then be applied fruitfully to firms.
If
networks are construed as social systems, then centrality indicates an actor’s
position in this overall system. For a board, centrality comes from being tied
to other boards through shared directors. Two measures of centrality have the
most intuitive appeal for boards (see Knoke and Burt 1983, for a compendium).
Degree is the simple count of ties—in short, how many other actors one is tied
to. For a board, degree is the total number of other boards on which its
directors serve. Prestige is the number of received ties (or in-degree)—how
frequently the actor is the object of ‘sent’ relations. Boards ‘send’ ties when
their executives sit on outside boards and ‘receive’ ties when executives of
outside firms serve as directors. CEOs of outside firms thereby contribute to a
board’s prestige.
Centrality
by these measures varies widely among firms. In 1994, Chemical Banking
Corporation was the most central American firm, sharing directors with
thirty-eight other large corporations.2 Three of its officers
collectively served on seven boards, and six executives of other firms served
on its board. Sara Lee was the third most central with thirty-three ties, and
Corning tied Union Pacific for tenth with twenty-eight ties. Conversely, of the
seven directors of Microsoft, only one served on the board of another large
corporation in 1994 (as an outside director), and Bill Gates (Microsoft’s CEO)
served on no other boards, making Microsoft one of the least central firms.
Walt Disney Corporation was also peripheral, sharing outside directors with
only two other large corporations. Like Gates, Disney CEO Michael Eisner served
on no outside boards.
As the
examples indicate, centrality is not simply a proxy for a firm’s current size,
performance, or a more nebulous ‘importance’. Correlations between a firm’s
number of interlocks and its sales, assets, market capitalization, and number
of employees in 1994 range between 0.39 and 0.45, and thus centrality is not
merely an artifact or indicator of size. Correlations with measures of
performance are modest or close to zero: centrality is correlated 0.12 with the
market-to-book ratio and under 0.05 with return on assets (ROA) and return on
equity. Interlock centrality is thus at best modestly related to other aspects
of a corporation’s importance.
One
might then be tempted to dismiss centrality as random or irrelevant. Yet it is
neither: a board’s centrality is highly stable over time and is demonstrably
important in shaping corporate governance. The stability of centrality is
quite striking. Of the ten most central corporations outside the insurance
industry in 1962, seven of them were still among the ten most central
corporations twenty years later (cf. Mintz and Schwartz 1985: table 7.3 with
Davis and Mizruchi 1999: table 1). And a corporation’s centrality in 1982 was
correlated at over 0.70 with its centrality in 1994, in spite of the fact that
the median board had experienced 75% turnover in membership during that time.
Well-connected boards tend to remain well connected independent of the
particular individuals serving as directors. There is thus an enduring status
order among corporate boards, indicating that, as in production markets, the interlock
network is a self-reproducing social structure (White 1981: 518).
The
stability of centrality would be curious but insignificant if being heavily
interlocked had no important impact on corporate action. But centrality has
documented effects on virtually every significant decision that boards make,
and the effects are precisely what one would expect from theory about the
impact of social structure on action. The diffusion of innovation literature,
for instance, finds that central actors are quicker to adopt innovations that
are consistent with the norms of a social system, and that when central actors
adopt it triggers subsequent adoptions by others because their adoption helps
legitimate the innovation (Rogers 1995). Both effects have been found repeatedly
in the interlock literature (Davis, Yoo, and Baker 2003). It is as if the firms
in the interlock network were individuals in a friendship network, with central
firms acting as the opinion leaders. Centrality is thus an indication of
status in the world of corporate governance.
The
decisions made by boards are also frequently steeped in ambiguity. Whether it
is appropriate to engage in takeovers or adopt a poison pill to ward them off;
compensate the CEO at a particular level or using a specialized incentive
contract; diversify into other industries or pare down to focus on a core
competence—all are open to debate, and all have been found to be influenced by
interlocks (see Mizruchi 1996 for a review). The microlevel mechanisms by which
interlocks have their effects are fairly mundane: experienced directors with
relevant information can say ‘Here’s what we did at my other company, and
here’s why we thought was a good idea’. Reasonable people can disagree about
such matters, and thus precedent—what other boards facing the same questions
did—helps resolve the ambiguity. Direct contact with other boards, via shared
directors, provides detailed information about others’ decision processes; the
actions of central (high status) boards provide evidence for the legitimacy of
a practice. Thus, one observes a surprising degree of conformity in the
governance practices of the largest American corporations, as boards follow the
precedents set by their immediate contacts and by high-status corporations
(Davis and Greve 1997).
Conformity in practice is
underlain by a common set of attitudes toward issues of immediate relevance
held by directors who serve on multiple boards (Neiva 1996). These seasoned
directors are particularly influential in boardroom discussions (Davis and
Greve 1997); moreover, they are particularly likely to be called to account by
other directors (Useem 1984). The late Harold Geneen of ITT wrote in reference
to directors that he called ‘asleep at the switch’:
What can spur them to
action? One thing: the fear of looking foolish. Most didn’t join the board to
make money or prove themselves; they joined for the prestige. To see that
prestige threatened is their worst nightmare. The dread of humiliation is their
one great motivating force. Thus, if a board member’s golf partners start
making wisecracks about the company that he is supposedly guiding, watch out.
He’ll get into fighting trim, fast. (Geneen 1997: 86)
Collectively,
members of central boards have ‘passive contact’ with many more directors than
do members of peripheral boards, and thus more frequently have to make sense of
their actions to directors of the other boards they serve on. This makes them
especially susceptible to following the ‘group standard’ of the corporate
elite.
This interpretation helps
make sense of the array of recent findings documenting the pervasive influence
of centrality, and interlocks more generally, on corporate decisionmaking.
Boards are embedded in social networks that follow the same regularities as
other social networks. Central boards have access to greater information and
are more susceptible to normative pressures than peripheral boards. They are
therefore more likely than peripheral boards to conform to the norms of the
social system in which they are embedded— for better or worse—and are quick to
adopt practices and structures considered appropriate. Other boards in turn
take their actions as signs of the legitimacy of a practice. Networks thereby
channel individual decisions into collective outcomes: one board’s decisions
about where to place the boundaries of the corporation, how to respond to the
threat posed by takeover, or to the opportunities created by a global economy,
become inputs into similar decisions by other boards. Yet the ‘morphology’ of the
corporate elite network is still dimly understood, in spite of its evident
importance. The process configuring the status order of the interlock
network—who becomes central, and why it is so stable—remains unclear.
We take
centrality to be an indicator of status and seek to understand the microprocess
of status attainment: what makes some boards persistently central? A board’s
centrality results from decisions by the board itself (e.g. to follow a
strategy of recruiting central or ‘prestigious’ directors) and by the directors
it attracts and retains. We consider centrality from both perspectives. Our
hypotheses are framed around two questions. First, what distinguishes boards
that appoint directors who already serve on many boards (thus increasing the
board’s degree) from those that serve on few or no other boards? Second, what
distinguishes boards that recruit CEOs of major corporations (increasing the
board’s prestige) from those that recruit non-CEOs?
With the exception of
financial hegemony theorists (Mintz and Schwartz 1985), prior theory on boards
of directors is largely silent with respect to centrality per se. Centrality
could reflect the quality of governance being provided by the board—either
positively or negatively. A corporation’s managers may try to lure outside
directors based on their likely appeal to shareholders and other
constituencies, as implied by managerialists. Much like the elaborate false
villages that Potemkin constructed to impress Catherine the Great, boards may
be assembled as an attractive facade for corporate governance. Directors who
serve on the boards of prominent firms, and particularly outside CEOs, may be
perceived as providing an implicit endorsement of the organization from these
other firms. Corporate managers’ incentives to pursue a Potemkin Village
approach increase to the extent that external displays of good faith are
required (Meyer and Rowan 1977). Corporations that are owned proportionally
more by institutional investors are perhaps more susceptible to scrutiny of
their boards, and we would expect that such firms would be prone to appoint central
directors. More direct forms of activism could also prompt the Potemkin Village
approach; thus, firms that have been targets of shareholder activism may also
seek to reassure their constituencies by appointing central directors.
Hypothesis 1a: Shareholder scrutiny will
increase the likelihood of appointment of central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 1b: Shareholder scrutiny will increase the
likelihood of appointment of outside CEOs to the board.
Agency theorists argue that
directors become central by demonstrating their expertise at corporate
governance. Multiple board seats are rewards for directors associated with
superior performance (Shivdisani 1993), while executives become CEOs by
compiling records of outstanding achievement at serving shareholder interests
(Fama 1980). Thus, central directors and CEOs should be those most able to
enhance the governance of a firm. Pressures on the board to recruit central
directors and CEOs increase to the extent that prior performance has been poor.
Firms with superior performance have little need to recruit ‘prestige’
directors, either as a signal to outside constituencies or in order to benefit
from their expertise. Conversely, firms with poor performance stand to gain the
most from improved governance, and thus have the greatest incentive to recruit
central directors.
Hypothesis 2a: Poor prior performance will
increase the likelihood of appointment of central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 2b: Poor prior performance will increase the
likelihood of appointment of outside CEOs to the board.
A third theoretical
rationale for seeking to recruit central directors is that, regardless of their
signaling value or their impact on governance per se, central directors
provide access to a broad range of business intelligence. Board interlocks
serve to enhance ‘business scan’, giving quick and reliable access to insider
information across a range of industries (Useem 1984). The studies cited
previously find that interlocks embed corporate boards in networks of
information flow, supporting the business scan interpretation. Bank boards in
particular are commonly composed of ‘corporate diplomats’ who are executives of
major firms and tend to serve on numerous boards (Mintz and Schwartz 1985).
Because the Clayton Act of 1914 prevents competing firms from sharing
directors, individuals who serve on multiple boards by definition do so across
different industries. Such individuals are an invaluable source of business
intelligence and are thus attractive directors for banks and other firms.
Financial institutions, particularly money center banks, historically used the
intelligence brought by their board members to guide their broad investment
policies (Mintz and Schwartz 1985). But any corporation that relies on
information about diverse industrial sectors would benefit from the expertise
of central directors. Thus, we expect to see firms seeking central directors
when they are more highly diversified, and when they operate in ‘network’
industries such as communications, financial services, transportation, and
business services.
Hypothesis 3a: Diversified firms will be
more likely to appoint central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 3b: Diversified firms will be
more likely to appoint outside CEOs to the board.
Hypothesis 4a: Firms in ‘network’ industries
will be more likely to appoint central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 4b: Firms in ‘network’ industries will be
more likely to appoint outside CEOs to the board.
Resource
dependence theory argues that interlocks reflect power and dependence
relations, and that firms invite executives of organizations on which they are
dependent to serve on the board in order to coopt them (Pfeffer and Salancik
1978). Inviting a representative of a constituency that needs to be coopted has
a venerable history, but pursuit of such ties can have potentially paradoxical
effects for firms’ centrality. On the one hand, firms that are in particularly
dependent situations should routinely seek to appoint ‘constraining’ directors.
On the other hand, the executives of powerful firms should routinely be sought
in order to coopt their employers. If all board invitations were accepted, then
both the weakest and most powerful boards would be central, as the executives
of powerful firms joined the boards of many firms that were dependent on them,
increasing centrality on both sides. There are two difficulties with this
account. First, cooptive ties are quite rare: in the mid-1990s, fewer than 5%
of large industrials had executives of firms in major buyer or supplier
industries represented on their board. Second, it is unclear what would
motivate executives of powerful corporations to serve on the boards of their
dependents, whereas the pitfalls of potential cooptation are clear.
The intuition behind this
approach, however—that ties to powerful actors are desirable—is surely correct.
Powerful actors make useful allies, even if efforts to coopt them are
problematic. We thus anticipate that the boards of powerful firms will be able
to recruit central and prestigious directors. Other things being equal,
whatever benefits board service achieves for oneself or one’s employer are more
likely to be available on the boards of large firms then small firms. Thus,
large firms should be better able to recruit prestigious directors than small
firms.
Hypothesis 5a: Large firms will be more
likely to appoint central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 5b: Large firms will be more likely to
appoint outside CEOs to the board.
Although size in this case
is likely to matter, the network properties of the board are also an important
consideration for potential directors. A board composed of corporate diplomats
is likely to be appealing to potential directors independent of the underlying
business: board meetings and the associated social events are an opportunity to
hobnob with the elite, which has rewards of its own. A directorship on a
central board is often a gateway to other board memberships, as the multiple
directors with whom one serves can provide entree to the other boards on which
they serve. It is likely that other business and social opportunities spring
from the same source. The attractions to ambitious individuals of service on a
central board are apparent (Mintz and Schwartz 1985: ch. 7). In addition,
because their net is cast broadly, central boards have an advantage in locating
and recruiting desirable directors through the first-hand experience of current
directors. In short, central boards are more attractive to potential central
directors and more likely to have contact with them. We therefore expect to see
a network ‘Matthew effect’ (Merton 1968; Podolny 1993): those that are already
central will be able to attract central directors, while those that are
peripheral will not.
Hypothesis 6a: Central firms will be more
likely to appoint central directors to the board.
Hypothesis 6b: Central firms will be more
likely to appoint outside CEOs to the board.
Our
interest is in unpacking the sources of interlock network centrality over time.
We did this by studying the board compositions of the several hundred largest
publicly-traded corporations in the United States in 1982, 1986, 1990, and 1994,
examining their centrality at each point in time as well as the character of
new board appointments between adjacent panels.
Our
sampling frame consisted of public corporations appearing in the Fortune 500
largest industrials or the 50 largest commercial banks, 25 diversified
financials, 25 retailers, or 25 transportation firms in 1980, 1986, 1990, or
1994. Firms appearing in earlier panels were included in subsequent panels even
if their revenues no longer warranted inclusion among the largest, while the
panels were expanded to include new entrants in later panels. Firms were
removed from the sample when they were no longer separate public corporations
(e.g. due to being absorbed by merger). A total of 647 firms were included in
the 1982 panel, 591 in 1986, 591 in 1990, and 822 in 1994. Four hundred and ten
firms appeared in all four panels, and their boards formed the core sample
(which we refer to as the ‘restricted sample’), although information about
other sampled firms was included when appropriate for the analysis. Because
centrality measures are sensitive to the size and boundaries of the network
measured, use of the restricted sample ensures that these measures are
maximally comparable over time.
We
analyzed several outcomes of interest. Overall centrality was measured in
several ways: using degree (i.e. the total number of other boards in a given
panel with which a firm shared directors, and the total number within the
restricted sample of 410), Bonacich centrality (calculated within the restricted
sample to maintain a consistent scaling), and received ties (or in-degree),
that is, the number of executives of other sampled firms that served on the
board, as an indicator of prestige.
The
Bonacich centrality measure is calculated by summing the Bonacich centrality
score for each of the other actors to which the focal actor is connected.
Since every actor’s Bonacich centrality depends on the corresponding centrality
scores for the other actors, this requires a simultaneous solution for the N equations. That solution
is calculated as the first eigenvector of the ‘characteristic equation’ of the
matrix Z, where Z is formed from the (N,N) matrix of observed ties by normalizing it
to be column stochastic (entries are nonnegative and sum to 1 within columns).
We used UCINET IV to calculate this measure for each panel year, including
only firms in the restricted sample in order to maintain maximum comparability
over time.
We
determined all new appointments of outside (nonexecutive) directors made by
firms appearing in adjacent panels (i.e. between 1982-6, 1986-90, and 1990-4).
Two outcomes were of interest: whether the new director was a CEO of one of the
other sample firms (in the full or restricted sample), and the number of other
sampled boards the new director served on at the beginning of the period. The
analyses asked the following question: Given that a board is making a new
appointment, what factors influence the likelihood that the new director is a
‘prestige’ or central director? The first outcome—appointing a CEO as an
outside director—increases the board’s prestige, while the second increases its
centrality. The character of such appointments thus directly determines the
board’s centrality.
Our
design allowed us to use lagged variables to model centrality and the character
of new appointments. Centrality was measured as described previously. Data on
board composition came from proxy statements as reported in Standard and Poor’s
Directory of Corporations, Executives, and Directors (for 1982) and Compact
Disclosure (for subsequent panels). Extensive computerized and hand-checking
routines ensured that directors and their positions as executives were uniquely
and accurately identified across firms and over time.
Size was
measured in three ways: using annual sales volume, number of employees, and
total assets. There is a slight preference for using employment as an indicator
of size, but we ran analyses using all three separately and note any
differences in results below. Performance was measured using the market to book
ratio (i.e. the market value of the company’s common stock divided by its book
or accounting value) and ROA (i.e. income before extraordinary items/total
assets). Because market to book is a ratio measure, it is susceptible to
extreme fluctuations when the denominator (book value of common) is close to
zero or negative. We therefore truncated this measure at zero and ten, so that
firms with nonmissing values below zero were recoded as zero and those above
ten were recoded as ten. Book value of total assets is considerably more
stable, of course, but because ROA and its variability differ substantially by
industry, we adjusted this measure by taking the z-score of a firm’s ROA
relative to that of other sampled firms in its primary 2-digit SIC industry for
that year. We then averaged this measure over three years to get an indication
of sustained performance relative to one’s industry competitors. All of these
measures were taken from Compustat and Compact Disclosure for various years.
Shareholder
scrutiny was measured in two ways. Ownership by institutional investors was the
percentage of a firm’s common shares held by 13F filers (i.e. entities holding
$100 million in equity assets, primarily banks, insurance companies, mutual
funds, and pension funds). This was measured using data reported in the
Spectrum directory of ownership for 1980 and Compact Disclosure for 1986 and
1990. Ownership by executives and directors came from the same sources for
1980, 1986, and 1990. Being a target of activist investors was measured using
the number of shareholder resolutions on governance issues appearing for
shareholder vote at each firm’s annual meeting. Resolutions can be included for
a vote at the annual meeting by any shareholders meeting certain conditions.
Shareholder resolutions are almost always opposed by management, and their rate
of passage is quite low, but they have been used by activists to draw attention
to firms that are considered to exhibit lax governance practices. Data on these
proxy resolutions came from various publications of the Investor Responsibility
Research Center, a not-for-profit organization that monitors issues of
corporate governance. Data availability was incomplete for earlier years, and
thus we included this variable only for the 1986-90 and 1990-4 panels. The
measure was the sum of shareholder resolutions for the first two years of each
observation period (i.e. 1986 + 1987 and 1990 + 1991).
Corporate diversification
was measured using the entropy measure for 1980, 1985, and 1990. Sales data by
segment came from Standard and Poor’s, Moody’s Industrial Manuals, and Compact
Disclosure. Because this measure was only available for industrial firms and
thus reduced the sample size, models including this variable were run separately.
Industry was coded using a dummy variable for firms operating in
telecommunications, transportation, financial services, securities, insurance,
and business services. We also ran separate models coding each of these
‘network’ industries separately. Finally, we coded a measure of corporate
reputation using Fortune Magazine’s annual survey of ‘America’s most admired
corporations’, in which the more admired firms were assigned higher scores.
This survey began in 1983, and so we used data for 1983, 1986, 1990, and 1994.
Because only a subsample of firms were included in these surveys, its inclusion
severely reduces our sample size, and we therefore report results on analyses
with and without this variable separately.
First, we analyze new
appointments of outside directors for non-banks. We compensate for unmeasured
firm-level effects by specifying a random-effects model, with the data
clustered by firm. We analyzed a firm’s ability to attract a CEO director using
a cross-sectional time-series probit regression in which the dependent variable
was coded as one if the new outside director was a CEO of one of the other
sampled corporations and zero otherwise. When the dependent variable was the
number of sampled boards the director served on, the corresponding Poisson
regression was used. In each case, we modeled either the appointment of a CEO
director or the appointment of a ‘central’ director as a function of the
independent variables described previously. We also controlled for director
turnover using the number of new appointments during the observation period.
Table
14.1 reports the results for the analyses of new director appointments. We find
that both measures of shareholder scrutiny (ownership by institutions
New CEO director
|
Degree of new director
|
|||||||||
Variable
|
||||||||||
Employees
|
0.0005 +
|
0.0000
|
0.0004
|
0.0006
|
0.0004
|
0.0002
|
0.0003
|
0.0002
|
0.0001
|
0.0001
|
(1.68)
|
(0.12)
|
(1.37)
|
(1.52)
|
(1.23)
|
(0.79)
|
(1.19)
|
(0.63)
|
(0.22)
|
(0.29)
|
|
Return on
|
0.1220*
|
0.1377*
|
0.1193*
|
0.1387*
|
0.1038
|
0.0705+
|
0.1254*
|
0.0658+
|
0.0811
|
-0.0081
|
assets
|
(2.99)
|
(2.92)
|
(2.76)
|
(3.05)
|
(1.32)
|
(1.86)
|
(3.08)
|
(1.67)
|
(1.92)
|
(-0.13)
|
Centrality
|
0.0382*
|
0.0436*
|
0.0387*
|
0.0385*
|
0.0303*
|
0.0438*
|
0.0421*
|
0.0437*
|
0.0454
|
0.0331*
|
(6.56)
|
(6.43)
|
(6.07)
|
(6.07)
|
(4.16)
|
(10.00)
|
(7.73)
|
(9.62)
|
(10.11)
|
(6.14)
|
|
Institutional
|
0.0034+
|
0.0051+
|
0.0028
|
0.0034+
|
0.0025
|
0.0044*
|
0.0047*
|
0.0030+
|
0.0035
|
0.0007
|
ownership
|
(1.78)
|
(1.94)
|
(1.44)
|
(1.66)
|
(0.88)
|
(2.60)
|
(2.23)
|
(1.77)
|
(1.92)
|
(0.28)
|
Shareholder
|
0.0120
|
0.0294*
|
||||||||
resolutions
|
(0.61)
|
(2.37)
|
||||||||
Reputation
|
0.0629
|
0.0300
|
||||||||
score
|
(1.03)
|
(0.67)
|
||||||||
Insider
|
-0.0012
|
- 0.0024
|
||||||||
ownership
|
(-0.38)
|
(-0.76)
|
||||||||
Diversification
|
0.0110
(0.18)
|
0.0352
(0.67)
|
||||||||
Industry
|
-0.0071
|
-0.0130
|
-0.0126
|
-0.0136
|
0.0070
|
0.0086
|
0.0082
|
0.0052
|
0.0015
|
0.0102
|
(-0.51)
|
(-0.85)
|
(-0.88)
|
(-0.77)
|
(0.33)
|
(0.56)
|
(0.51)
|
(0.34)
|
(0.08)
|
(0.53)
|
|
Constant
|
-1.5388*
|
-1.6758*
|
- 1.4726*
|
-1.5327*
|
- 1.8410*
|
-0.6100*
|
-0.6938*
|
-0.5111*
|
-0.5705
|
-0.4214
|
(-14.4)
|
(-11.2)
|
(-12.4)
|
(-12.1)
|
(-4.4)
|
(-5.9)
|
(-4.9)
|
(-4.6)
|
(-4.9)
|
(-1.4)
|
|
No. of directors
|
2902
|
2032
|
2663
|
2471
|
1392
|
2902
|
2032
|
2663
|
2471
|
1392
|
No. of firms
|
370
|
367
|
367
|
332
|
213
|
370
|
367
|
367
|
332
|
213
|
Chi squared
|
143.29
|
569.78
|
609.4
|
186.85
|
46.43
|
419.69
|
205.86
|
168.87
|
549.98
|
141.35
|
d.f.
|
10
|
11
|
11
|
9
|
10
|
10
|
11
|
11
|
9
|
10
|
*p < .05. + p < .10. Reported
significance levels are two-tailed.
|
and being subject to
shareholder resolutions) increased the centrality of new directors recruited,
consistent with Hypothesis 1a. Neither measure had a consistent positive
influence on CEO appointments, however, in contrast to Hypothesis 1b. The
effects of prior performance were quite the opposite of what we predicted in
Hypothesis 2: both CEOs and central directors were more likely to join the
boards of superior performers, not weak performers. We found little support for
Hypotheses 3 and 4: neither diversification nor operating in network industries
(those industries requiring the greatest crossindustry information) had a
consistent positive influence on appointments of CEOs or central directors. And
while there was little support for Hypothesis 5—large firms were not
significantly more likely to appoint CEOs or central directors than small
firms—there was quite consistent support for Hypothesis 6: centrality strongly
and consistently increased the probability that a new director would be a CEO
and the number of other board memberships held by the new director. Using
alternative measures of centrality (the Bonacich measure) and size (sales or
assets rather than employment) yielded substantively identical results.
Effects of Centrality on
Performance We wanted to determine what effect centrality has on subsequent
performance. Unreported analyses regressing a firm’s subsequent performance
(measured using the z-score of its ROA relative to its primary industry for
three years following the observation year) on its centrality, size, and
reputation found no significant effect for any measure of centrality. We did,
however, find a positive effect of reputation (the Fortune admiration score) on
subsequent performance.
Effects of Centrality on
Reputation We also treated a firm’s admiration score as the dependent variable. We
find that centrality has a significant positive effect on admiration. In other
words, net of the more predictable effects of size and performance, central
boards enhance a firm’s reputation, as one would expect given our
interpretation of centrality as status.
Our
findings indicate that corporate boards seek to appoint well-connected
directors to the extent that their need for displays of status are great—when
they are owned by institutional investors rather than individuals, and when
they have been the subject of governance-related shareholder proposals. They
are able to recruit such directors when their firms have a history of superior
performance, but most importantly when they are already central. Central boards
are presumably attractive to potential directors for several reasons and are
able to locate these directors because of their broad scan. Whatever the
reason, the one constant across all models was the finding that prior
centrality increased firms’ likelihood of appointing a status-enhancing
director. This was invariant to model specification and is quite robust to the
measure of centrality used.
Theorists
have speculated on the process by which outside directors are appointed—whether
these individuals are generally quiescent dupes of selfserving managers or
vigilant agents of their shareholder principals—but the evidence to date does
not support a simple interpretation in either direction (e.g. Zajac and
Westphal 1996). What motivates boards to seek particular candidates is
undoubtedly a mix of factors. But our results suggest two things that are new
to the literature. First, central directors appear to be appointed in part to
serve the ‘Potemkin Village’ function: they are most likely to be appointed by
corporations owned proportionally more by institutional investors and those
that have previously been subject to shareholder proposals on governance. It
is precisely these firms that experience the greatest scrutiny of their
governance practices, and whose boards therefore have the greatest pressures to
make displays of good faith to the shareholders that elect them. The displays
work to deflect scrutiny, if not to enhance governance: centrality evidently
increases the corporation’s esteem in the eyes of external constituencies while
leaving operating performance unchanged. These results parallel those by
Westphal and Zajac (1998): symbolic displays appear to be sufficient, even if
detached from substantive reform.
Second,
focusing on what the appointing firm gets out of recruiting a central director
tells only part of the story: one must also consider what is in it for the
director. Joining a corporation’s board may be attractive as a means to learn
from effective managers, because a firm is economically important, for career
advancement, or to gain the opportunity to associate with other corporate
diplomats and enhance one’s business scan (Useem 1984). Central firms, and
firms with a history of out-performing their industry, offer the best
opportunities to serve these interests and therefore have the most success at
attracting central directors, who presumably have their choice of which boards
to join. Conversely, firms with a history of poor performance, which might
benefit from the experiences of successful outside CEOs, have the least chance
of recruiting them to their boards.
Some
differences emerged between appointments of CEOs and central directors.
Institutional ownership had its greatest effect on the appointment of directors
holding multiple seats rather than on the appointment of CEOs, as did
shareholder resolutions. To the extent that the appointment of new directors is
intended to enhance status in the eyes of shareholders, it appears that central
directors are more frequently the object of this strategy than CEOs.
Conversely, CEOs may be more motivated by personal concerns— seeing first hand
how a successful firm is run, and networking.
The
effects of centrality on a firm’s performance and reputation were intriguing.
Neither central directors nor CEOs appeared to have a discernible impact on
corporate performance, bringing into question whether they are valid signals of
superior corporate governance from the perspective of shareholders. This null
effect was consistent across our measures of performance. In short, while good
prior performance may allow a firm to bag a CEO or central director, boards
composed of such individuals have no discernible impact on subsequent
operating performance. One might argue, following the logic of Demsetz and
Lehn (1985), that centrality adjusts to meet the level required for acceptable
performance; thus, in equilibrium centrality would have no relation to
performance. But this would imply that central directors are recruited when
performance is poor, bringing up subsequent performance to equilibrium levels.
As we have seen, however, the opposite is true. Board composition appears to be
a consequence, not a cause, of corporate performance.
Yet the
appearance of central directors on the board enhanced the perception of the firm
by analysts and other constituencies. They appear to serve as an effective
symbol of commitment to shareholder value, even if in fact their relation to
this construct is problematic. We must be cautious in interpreting this result,
as the Fortune survey appears to change its methodology from year to year, but
the result is tantalizing in light of our discussion of status.
The implication of all
these results in combination is that interlock network centrality is
self-reproducing: central boards appoint central directors, whereas peripheral
boards do not (see White 1981). Sustained poor performance will eventually
erode centrality by making it difficult to recruit central directors, but the
effect is rather modest compared with the impact of centrality. Performing two
standard deviations above one’s industry average for three years had about the
same estimated effect on CEO appointments as being one standard deviation
above the mean in centrality. Moreover, turnover rates on large corporate
boards were relatively low, particularly for central directors: the median
board in this sample replaced roughly 21% of its members every four years,
implying a relatively long lag period before a firm’s centrality catches up
with its performance. As a result, centrality is not a particularly reliable
indication of current or future corporate performance, although it may be
taken as such by outside constituencies. It is possible that centrality is a
valid signal of the quality of governance (as distinct from a corporation’s
economic performance), but this must be taken on faith, not evidence.
The
overall results support construing centrality as status, a signal of governance
quality when better information is not available. Outsiders have little direct
evidence on whether a board is a good one, at least prior to a governance
disaster. They are therefore compelled to rely on indirect indicators, such as
what other boards directors serve on, whether they are executives of other
major companies, and their age and tenure on the board—in other words, the
things reported on proxy statements. Outsiders take these signals seriously,
but there is little evidence that they should.
Boards
may seek to appoint central directors because of the need to demonstrate good
faith to shareholders and others, but whether intended or not, centrality has a
number of consequences. The flow of information and normative influence works
both ways: central boards have direct access to information and opinion about
the governance practices at many other firms, but they also become susceptible
to external demands as their directors are exposed to more occasions to explain
the board’s actions to outsiders. Central boards are thus quick to adopt
governance practices considered appropriate and more prone to conform to the
norms of the corporate elite, which need not map on to the expectations of
shareholders and other constituencies (Davis and Greve 1997). Attempts to
signal status by recruiting central directors may be directed at an audience of
shareholders, but centrality also acts as a signal to other boards, which look
to central firms for indications of the appropriateness of practices. Just as
markets are constituted of mutually- regarding producers arrayed in a status
hierarchy, the ‘governance market’ of interlocking boards is as well (White
1981; Podolny 1993).
Why does
centrality appear to affect the most important aspects of corporate
governance—including the ability to recruit high-profile directors—yet not
operating performance? We would argue that the answer turns on the kind of
information that can be transferred through ties such as interlocks. Outside
directors can convey concrete information about what other boards do and
opinions about the desirability of certain practices based on their experience,
and they can locate new director candidates and vouch for their character. But
they can’t bottle an elixir that will help the firm out-perform its
competitors. If this were the sort of knowledge that could be conveyed easily,
such as through board meetings or hiring consultants, presumably the firm
already would have implemented it. This situation parallels that described in
public schools by Meyer and Rowan (1977): in the absence of cause-and-effect
knowledge of how education occurs, schools seek to demonstrate their fitness
by external displays of conformity to procedure. Central boards serve their
legitimating function by being central, which signals their fitness to govern.
Absent more reliable signals, their constituencies appear to buy it.
Activist investors have
forwarded proposals for reforming corporate boards in order to enhance their performance.
Two things are notable about most of these proposals: (1) they almost always
prescribe standards for the small number of director attributes reported in the
proxy statement (imposing a mandatory retirement age; preferring CEOs to others
as outside directors; limiting the number of insiders; and so on) and not other
attributes, and (2) they are rooted not in solid evidence about what works but
‘common sense’. Our results suggest that boards can engage in displays of good
faith (e.g. recruiting high-profile directors), but these displays may not
have the intended
consequence (improving performance) and may well have unintended ones. For
better or worse, boards are social institutions first, positioning the firm in
a larger network that influences what information it gets and what kinds of
normative pressures it is susceptible to. The influence of network position on
governance practices is indisputable, but its impact on quality per se is
subtle at best.
1. There are several
disanalogies between the governance market and other markets, although scholars
have discussed a market for corporate directors (Fama and Jensen 1983). To
start, any competition among governance producers is muted at best. The
boundaries of the market are largely unimportant, in contrast to the boundaries
of industrial markets. What is produced is intrinsically intangible and
evaluations of quality are particularly ambiguous. Finally, economic cost is
largely irrelevant. Yet the notion of board status is intuitively plausible and
helps explain several empirical regularities both in shareholder perceptions of
board quality and in the dynamics of the interlock network.
2. The sample network for the
descriptive statistics in this paragraph consists of 822 American corporations
that were the publicly-traded members of the 500 largest manufacturers (by
revenues), 100 largest commercial banks, 100 largest service firms, 50 largest
retailers, 50 largest diversified financials, and 50 largest transportation
companies in 1994, as well as 76 firms that had been among the largest during
the 1980s but had dropped off the list.
沒有留言:
張貼留言