Preface
Global finance is big business. Really big
business. The bond rating agencies that are the subject of this book maintain
ratings on $30 trillion worth of debt issued in American and international
markets. These markets are surely too big for us to ignore if we want to
understand how our world works.
Not only is global finance big, but it touches us all. The fortunes of currencies— and of banks and the markets for
securities -affect our lives every day. They affect the interest rates we pay
for our credit card debt, those for our house mortgage, and the return on our
pension fund.
A lot of people
are confused by how finance works. It appears very technical. Because finance
has this image, many prefer to leave
it to "the experts." But we must not allow
ourselves to do so. Like war, the institutions and processes of global finance are
too important to leave to professionals to figure out. This book is an effort
to cross the boundary into expert territory and identify the broader political
significance of these seemingly areane technical institutions.
Sir Robert
Muldoon, prime minister and minister of finance of New Zealand, 1975—84, may
not be a frequent beneficiary of scholarly thanks, but this book would not
exist at all had it not been for him. Although I never met the man, his
relations with the bond rating agencies first made me think that understanding
these institutions might be important in the post-Bretton Woods era. Muldoon,
short of stature and wide of girth, was energetic, intelligent, and truculent.
Very little cowed him. Noted exceptions were the rating agencies, which Muldoon
seemed to think were very important. He left an impression on rating officials
that was still evident several years after his tenure ended, as I discovered
during interviews on Wall Street. Muldoon's views had an impact on me as well.
I was very
fortunate in the intellectual and institutional support that came my way as
this book developed. Robert Cox, Stephen Gill, and David Leyton-Brown (DLB) all
had a major influence. I could not have asked for more challenging scholarly
training or better mentoring. I also thank DLB for the generous financial support
he provided in connection with researeh funded by the Social Sciences and
Humanities Researeh Council of Canada, without which my fieldwork in Japan
would not have been possible. At York University in Toronto, the faculty and
staff of the Department of Political Science, the Faculty of Graduate Studies,
Stong College, and the York Centre for International and Security Studies
supported this researeh in many ways, providing office space, fieldwork grants,
and conference funding to test my initial ideas.
At the
University of Warwick in England, where I have worked since 1995,1 am thankful
for two researeh development grants, which allowed me to undertake supplemental
fieldwork. I also appreciate the financial support for conference participation
generously provided by the Department of Politics and International Studies.
The Warwick Center for the Study of Globalisation and Regionalisation provided
support for attendance at a conference on rating agencies held at New York
University's Stern School in 2001. At Warwick, I have been fortunate to teach
a graduate class on the politics of global finance for some years. Many
students have offered valuable insights while reading and discussing my journal
articles on rating. Joe Horneck and Belkys Lopez are notable among their
colleagues for bringing useful documentary sources to my attention. Paola
Robotti, a Warwick doctoral candidate, applied her considerable skill to
improve my primitive efforts at drawing figures.
During the
closing stages of this project, I was fortunate to spend a sabbatical year at
Harvard University, as a visiting scholar at the Weatherhead Center for International
Affairs. Jeffry A. Frieden and James A. Cooney were instrumental in making
this happen and helped make it a most valuable experience. While at Harvard, I
was resident at Winthrop House, where Karen Reiber, Martine van Ittersum, David
Simms, and Enoch Kyerematen made a big difference to my experience.
Many people in
the global academic community helped with this book in one way or another. In
Canada, Eric Helleiner, Louis W. Pauly, Chris Robinson, A. Claire Cutler, and
Ricardo Grinspun were key. In the United States, I greatly benefited from the
interest of James N. Rosenau, Raymond D. "Bud" Duvall, Craig N.
Murphy, Rawi E. Abdelal, James H. Mittelman, Timothy J. McKeown, Kenneth P
Thomas, Jeffry A. Frieden, Peter Gourevitch, Richard W. Mansbach, Yale H.
Ferguson, Michael Schwartz, Mark Amen, Virginia Haufler, Kathryn Lavelle, and
"Skip" McGoun. In Europe, I learned much from Ronen Palan, Jan Aart
Scholte, Susan Strange, Dieter Kerwer, Torsten Strulik, Helmut Willke, Oliver
Kessler, Philip G. Cerny, Donald MacKenzie, Tony Payne, Marieke de Goede, Peter
Burnham, Henk Overbeek, and Kees van der Pijl. Frank and Patrick McCann provided
expert photographic input.
I have many
debts to acknowledge for the help I received during my field researeh.
Particularly kind were Leo C. O'Neill and Cathy Daicoff of Standard &
Poor's, and David Stimpson of Moody's Investors Service. I met Mr. O'Neill,
president of Standard & Poor's, near the start and the end of the project,
and at each meeting he was forthcoming and incisive. Most helpful in the final
years of my researeh was David Levey of Moody's. David is a great source of
knowledge and good judgment about the rating business and its challenges, as
well as a scholar and political economist himself. I learned a great deal from
him. Chris Mahoney, also of Moody's, provided important aid. Takehiko Kamo,
before his early death a professor in the Faculty of Law at the University of
Tokyo, assisted my researeh in Japan, sponsoring my stay at the International
House of Japan. Donald J. Daly, Hiroharu Seki, and Seiji Endo helped with
contacts in Japan.
In addition to
anonymous reviewers, several scholars read the entire manuscript. I am greatly
indebted to Benjamin J. Cohen, Tony Porter, Richard Higgott, Randall Germain,
and Edward Cohen for their useful comments. They influenced me in many ways.
Friends and
associates also supported me during the researeh and writing of this work.
Especially important were Steve Patten, Graham Todd, Edward Comor, Robert
O'Brien, J. Magnus Ryner, Martin Hewson, Liliana Pop, Randall Germain, Peter
Burnham, Shirin Rai, and my IPMS Mercia friends in Warwickshire.
Peter J.
Katzenstein and Roger Haydon made a major contribution to my thinking about
how this book should be organized. Their belief in the project and their
practical impact cannot be underestimated.
Finally, my deep
thanks go to the Wilson sisters. Delphine, Helen, Nancy, and Frances pushed me
to defend my early ideas about politics, most memorably around the gas lamps
and dinner tables at Mataikona. They inspired me, although it has taken me
thirty years to appreciate fully their significance.
Timothy J.
Sinclair
Kenihvorth, Warwickshire
Chapter 1 Introduction
We live again in a
two-superpower world. There is the U.S. and there is Moody's. The U.S. can
destroy a country by levelling it with bombs: Moody's can destroy a country by
downgrading its bonds.
Thomas L.
Friedman, New York Times, 1995
Contemporary
American power is obvious to the casual observer. If you want concrete evidence
of U.S. superpower status, take a trip to southern Arizona. Outside the city
of Tucson is AMARE, the USAF "boneyard," the greatest collection of
mothballed warplanes on Earth.1 If an airplane was a part of the
American war machine during the past thirty years you will probably find it
here, patiently awaiting its fate in the blazing Sonoran desert sun, together
with some three thousand others. In this place, B-52 Stratofortresses, like
those that dropped bombs on Vietnam, Afghanistan, and Iraq, and which were held
in readiness for nuclear retaliation during the Cold War, are broken up, their
shattered fuselages and wings displayed for the benefit of Russian spy
satellites documenting the fulfillment of Strategic Arms Reduction Treaty
(START) obligations. A-10 Thunderbolt IIs, the venerable "Warthog"
tank-busters of Gulf Wars I and II, now expected to be in the USAF inventory
until 2028, stand row upon row in the searing desert heat, quietly awaiting
redeployment. Other "hogs,”based at nearby Davis-Monthan Air Force Base,
fly low overhead, silently circling the University of Arizona campus. In this
arsenal, the embodiment of a Tom Clancy or Don DeLillo novel, the basis of America's
superpower status could not be clearer.
But things are different when it comes to the "second
superpowers," the major bond rating agencies—Moody's
Investors Service (Moody's), its competitor, Standard & Poor's (S&P),
the smaller and less important Fitch Ratings (Fitch), and the multitude of
minor domestic rating agencies around the globe. They operate in a very
different world. Their arsenal is an
occult one, largely invisible to all but a few most of the time.2 Financial stress expands the size of
the group aware of the agencies: in 2002, Europe had its highest-ever level of
defaults, up to $15 billion from $4 billion in 2001. To the people directly
concerned with matters of financial health— chief financial officers, budget
directors, Treasury officials, and increasingly even politicians—rating
agencies are well known.3 In this book the world of these second
superpowers is explored: the basis of their power, the nature of their
authority in financial markets, and implications of their judgments for
corporations, municipal governments, and sovereign states.
In examining
this world, I argue that rating agency activities reflect not the "correctness"
or otherwise of rating analyses but
instead the store of expertise and intellectual authority the agencies
possess. Market and government actors take account of
rating agencies not because the agencies are right but because they are thought to be an authoritative source of
judgments, thereby making the agencies key organizations controlling access to
capital markets. It is the esteem enjoyed by rating
agencies—a characteristic distributed unevenly in modern capitalism—that this
book explores, rather than whether agency ratings are actually valid.
A further claim
made here is that this consequential speech has semantic content or meaning.
That content, developed within the framework of rating orthodoxy delineated in
chapter 3, is not purely technical but is linked to social and political
interests. Although it is tempting to suggest that those interests are not
related to location, the American origins of the rating agencies are relevant.
Changes on Wall
Street and in other global financial centers increased the significance of
Moody's and S&P during the 1990s. The destruction of the World Trade Center
in 2001 did not reverse this trend.4 Since the terrorist attacks,
international trade and financial transactions have increased.5The
broad context for the increased role of rating is the process of financial
globalization that began in the 1970s.
Financial
globalization encompasses worldwide change in how financial markets are
organized, increases in financial transaction volume, and alterations in government
regulation. As discussed here, the concept is more comprehensive than Armijo's
specification of financial globalization as "the international integration
of previously segmented national credit and capital markets."6
In financial globalization, markets are increasingly organized in an
"arms length" way. Institutions that once dominated finance and were
politically consequential, as a result, now have other roles.
Cross-border
transactions have, of course, massively increased since capital controls were
liberalized in most rich countries during the late 1970s and 1980s. The
regulation of financial markets has also changed form since then. Though
increasingly detailed, regulation is typically implemented by market actors.
Government agencies create and adjust the self-regulatory framework as
circumstances merit. In this environment, new financial products and strategies
emerge frequently. Market volatility is associated with these developments, as
is a sense that governments themselves are increasingly subject to the
judgments of speculators and investors.
The changes in
market organization have been significant. Commercial banks used to be the
institutions that corporations, municipalities, and national governments
sought out in order to borrow money. Today, in a process known as disinter-
mediation, bonds and notes sold on
capital markets are displacing traditional bank loans as the primary means of
borrowing money. In a related process, securitization,
mortgages, credit card receivables, and even bank loans are being transformed
into tradeable securities that can be bought and sold in capital markets. This
does not mean banks are of little importance in global financial markets. It means that judgments about who receives credit
and who does not are no longer centralized in banks, as was the case in the
past.
Over the past
decade, the liberalization of
financial markets has made rating increasingly important as a form of private
regulation.7 States
have had to take account of private sector judgments much more than in the
heavily controlled postwar era.8 Liberalization of the financial
markets have also increased exposure to risk and therefore the importance of information,
investigation, and analysis mechanisms. Outside the rich countries,
liberalization has been pursued by developing- country governments in Asia and
Latin America that have sought to create local capital markets to finance
investment in new infrastructure and industrial production. The importance of
these new markets is that their operatives want information about the
creditworthiness of the corporations and governments that seek to borrow their
money. As things stand, market operatives get some of this information, in the
form of bond ratings, from Moody's and S&P.
The two major
U.S. rating agencies pass judgment on around $30 trillion worth of securities
each year.9 Of this $30 trillion, around $107 billion worth of debt
issued by 196 bond issuers was in default in 2001—a figure up sharply from
2000, when 117 issuers defaulted on $42 billion.1,1 Ratings, which
vary from the best (AAA or "triple A") to the worst (D, for default),
affect the interest rate or cost of borrowing for businesses, municipalities,
national governments, and, ultimately, individual citizens and consumers. The
higher the rating, the less risk of default on repayment to the lender and,
therefore, other things being equal, the lower the cost to the borrower.
Rating scales are described in more detail in chapter 2.
The phenomenon
investigated here is usually thought of as a technical matter. But this is
largely a nontechnical book. An accurate, meaningful understanding of bond
rating requires a broader view than the technical, just as an understanding of
war cannot be limited to the analysis of military maneuvers or logistics.
Hence, this book considers not just how ratings are done but also the purposes attributable to the rating process,
the power and authority of the agencies, the implications of rating judgments,
and the problems that may bring change to the world of ratings.
Widespread
misunderstandings exist about the way capital markets and their institutions
work and shape the world. These markets are complex and seemingly areane. The
amount of money involved is titanic and likely awesome to all but the richest
inhabitants of the planet. Many think these markets shape economic and
political choices in an objective way, much as the laws of physics shape the
universe.11 But the unqualified influence of markets and market
institutions in recent years has not always been evident. For a time, during
the New Deal era of the 1930s and the years of postwar prosperity in the West,
a greater degree of public control tempered these global forces. U.S. and other
Western governments developed welfare programs and policy measures to insulate
their populaces from the vagaries of capital markets. But the constraints, so
the story goes, were artificial and, since the 1970s, have been challenged.
Financial markets have again opposed the dictates of elected authorities and
voters, to assume their "rightful place" in the scheme of things.
Now, we are told by the popular and the scholarly press, there is no escaping
these impersonal forces.
As an
explanation of financial globalization, this sort of mechanistic view is not
adequate. A technical understanding of the forces that constrain our economic
and political choices is necessarily limited. This view assumes markets develop
in ways beyond the influence of citizens, that people should simply allow
things to take their "natural" course—financial globalization is inevitable. This is a key point. Much that is written about financial markets,
even by people who recognize the political consequences of these markets,
misses the fundamentally social character of what happens inside the markets
and their institutions.12
The assumption
in established texts is that markets reflect fundamental economic forces, which
are not subject to human manipulation. But this view does not take account of
the fact that people make decisions in financial markets in anticipation of
and in response to the decisions of others.13 In this book, the social nature of global finance gets
particular emphasis. The social view of finance
suggests that in situations of increased uncertainty and risk, the institutions
that work to facilitate transactions between buyers and sellers have a central
role in organizing markets and, consequently, in governing the world.14
Financial markets are more social—and less spontaneous, individual, or
"natural"—than we tend to believe.
The role of
rating agencies is not mechanistically determined, either. Many financial
markets survived and flourished in the past without them. Typically, banks assumed
the credit risk in the relationship between those with money to invest and
those wishing to borrow. Alongside banks, traditional capital markets relied on
borrowers who were well known and trusted names in their communities. But
rating has increasingly become the norm as capital markets have displaced bank
lending and as the trust implicit in these older systems has broken down. Rating serves a purpose in less socially embedded
capital markets, where fund managers are under pressure to demonstrate they are
not basing their understanding of the creditworthiness of investment
alternatives on implicit trust in names but use a recognized, accepted
mechanism.
At least three
other ways of doing the existing work of the rating agencies can be imagined. The first is self-regulation by debtors. Much like the professional bodies for physicians, architects, and
lawyers, a debtor-based system of credit information could provide data to the
markets. Although this system might not be independent, collective self-interest
would mitigate the tendency to self-serving outputs, much as is the case with
professional self-regulation. Second,
nonprofit industry associations could undertake or coordinate creditworthiness
work. Good precedents already exist in countries where
nonprofits enforce some national laws, such as in the case of animal welfare.
The nonprofit model offers to eliminate some conflict of interest tensions
implicit in charging debtors for their ratings. Third, governments could collectively take on the job, perhaps
in the form of a new international agency. The
International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) is already
involved in discussions about rating standards and codes of conduct.'1
The World Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and regional development
banks could encourage local rating agencies in emerging markets to issue
ratings. Such an arrangement would be independent of particular debtors and
less subject to conflict of interest concerns, especially if not funded by
rating fees.
John Moody, a
muckraking journalist, Catholic convert, and credit analyst, published The
Masters of Capital in 1919. In this volume he chronicled the construction of
the railroad and steel trusts in the United States, and the links between these
interests and Wall Street during the "robber baron" years, the era
between the end of the Civil War and 1914.16 Moody investigated the
capitalism of his day by looking at great entrepreneurs. Here,
twenty-first-century capitalism is examined through analysis of institutions
rather than the actions of "great men," an ontology more appropriate
to present conditions.17
Within
contemporary capitalism, rating agencies do not represent the only institutionalization
of power, nor are they all-seeing, all-knowing, all-powerful. This volume is
not an account of a conspiracy. The issue of power and authority inside
capitalism today is its focus, just as Moody sought insight into the business
power of his time. Ironically, however, the watchdogs of his day are the
subject here.
Characteristics of the Rating Agencics
Rating agencies are some of the most
obscure institutions in the world of global finance. Everyone knows what a bank
is. Most people can explain what an insurance company does or offer a rough
outline of an accountant's activities. But rating agencies are specialist
organizations whose purpose and operations are little known outside their
immediate environment.
The discussion
is not concerned with the merits of the agencies from an economic or policy
perspective, to determine whether they are "good" or "had."
The purpose, based on the agencies' growing impact, is to evaluate their role
in financial globalization. The
agencies are influential mechanisms of financial globalization, shaping what
governments (at all levels) do and corporate behavior, too. Hence, an understanding of the motivations, objectives, and
constraints on these institutions is worthwhile.
Although they
are often confused with Moody's and S&P, institutions such as Dun and
Bradstreet, which undertake the mercantile rating of retailers for suppliers,
are excluded from the analysis. Also excluded are corporations that issue
credit ratings on individual consumers, such as Experian.18 Many of
the broader processes identified here are evident in these institutions, but
these other raters are not central to the organization of capital markets.
Rating agencies are examined in the context of their work with institutions in
the capital markets, including municipalities, corporations and sovereign
states, because that is where rating has the most impact.
What do the
raters actually do? The agencies claim to make judgments on the
"future ability and willingness of an issuer to make timely payments of
principal and interest on a security over the life of the instrument."19 Ostensibly, this is a narrow remit. The more
likely it is that "the borrower will repay both the principal and interest,
in accordance with the time schedule in the borrowing agreement, the higher
will be the rating assigned to the debt security."20 The
agencies are adamant about what a debt rating is not. According to Standard
& Poor's, a rating is "not a
recommendation to purchase, sell, or hold a security, inasmuch as it does not
comment as to market price or suitability for a particular investor," because investors' willingness to take risks varies.21
In other words, a credit rating should form just part of the information
investors use to make decisions. Rating agencies
themselves do not claim to provide more than some of the information investors
need.
As noted,
financial globalization has widened the scope of the agencies' work. The prevailing objective, for both major agencies,
is to achieve globally comparable ratings. If an AA on
a steel company in South Korea is equivalent in credit-risk terms to AA on a
pulp mill in British Columbia or to a similar rating on a software producer in
California, investors can make global choices. In recent years, the agencies
have also sought to provide ratings that are comparable within specific national
contexts. New York, however, very much remains the analytical center, where
rating expertise is defined and reinforced internally through the agencies'
established training cadres and standard operating procedures.
The agencies
produce ratings on corporations, financial institutions, municipalities, and
sovereign governments in terms of long-term obligations, such as bonds, or
short-term ones like commercial paper.
Once issued,
rating officials maintain surveillance over issuers and their securities. They
warn investors when developments affecting issuers—their tax base, say, or
their market—might lead to a rating revision, either upward or downward. As
will be seen, this surveillance aspect of rating work is a key one, just as
Pauly has shown in the context of International Monetary Fund monitoring.22
Rating agency surveillance shapes
the thinking and action of debt issuers. It also shapes
the expectations of investors, who want the agencies to forensically scrutinize
issuers and who complain vociferously when this scrutiny seems less than they
think it ought to be. Investors seem to expect rating agencies to play the role
of the prison guards in Bentham's perfect penitentiary, the panopticon.23
What product do
the agencies sell? They purvey both professional, expert knowledge in the form
of analytical capacities and local knowledge of a vast number of debt security
issuers. The disinter mediation process heightens the role of bond rating
agencies. It increases their analytical and local specialization absolutely,
because they now rate more issues in more locations, and relatively, because
with the growth of capital markets, comparable specialists (bank credit
analysts are the obvious example) have become less important as gatekeepers.24
Both Moody's and
S&P are headquartered in New York. Both global agencies have numerous
branches in the United States, Europe, and emerging markets. A distant third
in the market is Fitch Ratings, a unit of Fimalac SA of Paris. Domestically
focused agencies have developed in OECD countries and in emerging markets since
the mid-1990s.25
Public panics or
crises about rating miscalls are the most significant challenge the agencies
face. Crises erode and even threaten to shatter the reputational assets the
agencies have built up since the interwar period. The 1990s and the first years
of the new millennium saw more of these events, when volatility grew along with
financial globalization. Threatening events included Mexico's financial crisis
of 1994-95, Asia's financial crises of 1997-98, and Russia's default in 1998.
Derivatives and other innovations stimulated corporate and municipal scandals
and financial collapses in the United States, including the bankruptcy of Enron
Corporation in late 2001. The new millennium was marked by the $141 billion
sovereign debt default of Argentina in 2001-02.26
Two main
strategies characterize the agencies' responses to these legitimacy crises.
Like other financial industry institutions, the agencies try to keep up with financial innovation,
spending large sums on staff training and hiring. They
push development of their own products. The agencies have created new symbols
to indicate when, for example, ratings are based on public information only
and do not reflect confidential data (in the case of Standard & Poor's).
The agencies, especially Moody's, have
sought to change their cloistered, secretive corporate cultures and, since
1997, have become more willing to set out a clear rationale for their ratings. That strategy may have much to do with managing public expectations
of the agencies.
How do the
agencies relate to governments? Despite assumptions to the contrary, the work
of rating agencies, in terms of their criteria and decision-making, is not
regulated seriously anywhere in the developed world. Indeed, tight regulation
would potentially destroy the key thing agencies have to sell: their
independent opinion on market matters. However, some process by capital market
regulatory agencies of "recognizing" rating agencies' activities is
customary around the world.27 This recognition is especially
significant in the United States, where many states have laws governing the
prudential behavior of public pension funds.28 In these cases, the agencies' outputs are recognized as
benchmarks limiting what bonds a pension fund can buy.
A central
feature of United States and other countries' processes of governmental
recognition is regulators' reliance on wide market acceptance of a firm's
rating. In turn, the agencies resist recurrent efforts to develop more invasive
forms of regulation and hold up the public standard of market acceptance as the
best test of their quality. They also oppose deeper incorporation of their
ratings as benchmarks in law. Developing country governments often make ratings
of domestic debt issues compulsory as a way of promoting the development of
liquid, transparent capital markets.
Increasingly,
ratings are key elements in transnational financial regulation. In 2001, the
Bank for International Settlements proposed replacing established capital
adequacy standards with a new system in which ratings play a significant role
in estimating the risk exposure of banks.29
Rating and Politics
Nuances of power and authority heighten the
significance of rating. Rating
agencies do possess, via rating downgrades, the capacity at times to coerce
borrowers eager to obtain scarce funds. But relations
between rating agencies and other institutions are more often about changing
world views and influence than "power wielding." On the one hand, the
influence of the rating agencies grows as new borrowers look to raise funds in
lower-cost capital markets rather than borrow from banks in the traditional
way. In this environment, the number of agency branches is expanding, and the
role of Moody's and Standard & Poor's is more significant: the agencies put
a price on the policy choices of governments and corporations seeking funds.
On the other
hand, many government administrations, particularly in the developing world
and Japan, have encouraged the formation of national bond rating agencies.
These initiatives are intriguing. They suggest that the loss of government
policy autonomy implied in the establishment of rating has not been imposed on
governments but is actually something states have sought, even promoted.
Hence, a view of rating simply as a coercive force does not capture the whole
story Consideration also must be given to where rating shapes, limits, and
controls—often in connection with the generation of authority—rather than the
brute application of power. Elaborating this consideration is a key focus of
this book.
Analytical Approach
In this book specific institutions and
associated "micropractices" at the core of contemporary capitalism
are examined, in particular the "reconfiguring" effect these institutions
and practices have on global economic and political life within sovereign
states.30 Natural science seeks to establish universal laws and
considers specific events in terms of these laws. The objective is always
generalization, and many social scientists have followed this path. Here, the
purpose is similar to "process tracing," the historical development
of interpretive frames actors use to understand the world.31
Specific events,
institutions, and ways of thinking are associated with rating agencies. The
focus on particular aspects of rating agencies—rather than on the positing of
universal laws about agencies "in general"—means that the research
design of this book is "realistic" and inductive. The design does not
aspire to the "hypo- thetico-deductive mode of theory construction"
that dominates much of social science.32 One way of viewing this
book is as an exploration or probe that may help to create the basis for future
hypothesis testing.
Substantively,
this investigation is concerned with the veracity of different approaches, or
general theoretical orientations, to motivation and action that are the subject
of contemporary debate in the field of international political economy (IPE).
These general theoretical orientations offer heuristics, in the form of
relevant variables and causal patterns that provide guidelines for research.
IPE has been
dominated by rationalist approaches such as realism and liberalism, informed by
economics, in which the heuristic is the struggle of rational actors with fixed
preferences around scarce resources. This heuristic can be applied to any number
of problems as a guiding set of assumptions about what likely motivates an
action." Here, this dominant rationalist lens is compared and contrasted
with a very different general theoretical orientation.
This second
approach draws on economic and organizational sociology and on the social
sciences, other than economics. Rationalist approaches adopt the assumption
that there is a one-to-one match between imputed material interests and social
action. The constructivist approach can complement the instrumental
cause-effect focus of rationalism. The heuristic focuses on processes through
which the preferences and subsequent strategies of actors (such as corporations
and states) are socially constructed, varying over time and space, and defining
the identity or nature of the actors in relation to others.34The
norms, identity, knowledge, and culture that comprise intersubjective
structures—things held constant in rationalism—are among the things that
constitute or regulate actors in this general theoretical orientation.35
Both rationalism
and constructivism are, as it is seen in subsequent chapters, essential for
understanding bond rating agencies. The constructivist lens has, however, so
far been neglected in IPE, to our detriment.36 In part, this book is
an effort to correct that omission and to demonstrate the analytical
contribution constructivist social science can make to IPE research.
International political
economy started as a study of foreign economic policy, mainly of the United
States and the European powers. These origins have led to IPE being dominated
by the view that markets are very different from the typical institutionalized
manifestations of politics, like political parties and government bodies such
as houses of representatives. Unlike most economists, many IPE specialists have
been interested in the interaction of the economic and political spheres (understood
as different motivations), which scholars with diverse approaches have thought
were neglected.
Only through an
analysis of this interaction could an understanding of international economic
relations be formed, one that included many more variables than those
economists have focused on. This area of analysis has contributed much to our
understanding of the developing global order since World War II, especially of
the creation and decay of the Bretton Woods regime. But global markets have
developed and states have changed in form and behavior during the three decades
since the end of that regime. Consequently, the strict separation of IPE
subject matter, into a "states" category on the one hand and
"markets" on the other, has become problematic. Increasingly, IPE
thinkers have been concerned with intermediary institutions that are neither
states nor markets but interact with both.37 Some scholars have also
looked at the economic sphere, to reappraise inherited notions of what markets
are and how they work.38
Economic
sociology offers an alternative theoretical source for analytical insight.39
The prime benefit it offers in abstract terms is to ground the agentcentric understanding
(of states, of companies, of individuals) implicit in traditional IPE in a
structure emerging from social relations. Waltz and international relations
Neorealism offered a sense of structure. But that structure did not encompass
market relations and tended to minimize the role of actors other than states,
even if the formal account of the approach gave space to other agents.40
By contrast with
the Neorealist vision of an anarchy of self-regarding units, the notion of
"embeddedness" Granovetter identified—a key concept in economic sociology—sought
to link institutions to the social relations in which they existed.41
In this understanding, economic life
was not separate from society like a free-standing machine but was linked to
historical and cultural circumstances and, therefore, variable over time and
space.42 However,
despite embeddedness, economic and institutional sociology has produced
"evidence of global cultural homogenization."43 This
process of change is linked to pervasive myths or mental frameworks, which
legitimate specific organizational forms (and negate others).
Mental or
intersubjective frameworks are just as consequential as other social
structures. As W. I. Thomas noted in 1928, "If men [sic] define situations
as real, they are real in their consequences." Thomas claimed that people
respond not just to objective things, like mountains and automobile accidents,
"but also, and often mainly," to their collective attribution of
meaning to the situation. As Coser points out, if people think witches are
real, "such beliefs have tangible consequences."44
The importance
of mental frameworks is reflected within institutions. Meyer and Rowan argue
that organizations and how they are structured reflect not the efficient
undertaking of their function but the myths or mental frameworks that depict a
public story about the organization.41 Internal rules and
organizational forms within institutions reflect "the prescriptions of
myths." These rules and organizational forms demonstrate that the
organization is acting "in a proper and adequate manner." By
conforming to the myth, the organization protects itself from interrogation.
The key process is identifying elements of the myth and then reconfiguring the
organization around them. Organizations, Meyer and Rowan suggest, typically
face dilemmas between the prescriptions of these elements and their internal,
shared sense of what they are really supposed to be about, and also between
diverse competing myths held by different parts of society, such as
government, interest groups, and market associations.46
Professional
judgment and analysis—and public expectations about its development and
standards—is a key, societally legitimated rationalized element of the rating
agencies' mental framework. One conception of how this framework can be
understood in its wider social context is through what Peter Haas and his
fellow contributors have called epistemic communities.47 Haas
defines epistemic communities as "networks of knowledge-based
experts" that address complex, seemingly technical problems. The
"recognized expertise and competence" of these professionals give
them an authoritative claim to offering good advice, and their control of
expertise is "an important dimension of power."
Haas suggests
four features of epistemic communities: a shared set of normative and principled beliefs, shared
causal beliefs, shared notions of validity in the area of expertise, and a
"common policy enterprise" connected to enhancing human welfare. Epistemic communities neither guess nor produce data but interpret
phenomena. The major role of the communities lies in ostensibly "less
politically motivated cases," where they introduce a range of policy
alternatives.48 The communities differ from the concept of
profession in that they share normative commitments but such commitments may
develop within professions (for example, the subset of economists concerned
with economic inequalities).
A normative
element also distinguishes epistemic communities from other concepts such as
policy entrepreneur.49Haas argues that the communities do not behave
as rational choice or principal-agent theory would predict because of the
central role attributed to their beliefs. Epistemic communities are important
in themselves because they "convey new patterns of reasoning" to
policymakers and "encourage them to pursue new paths of policymaking,"
with unpredictable outcomes.50
The concept of
epistemic communities is relevant to this book's focus on patterns of
reasoning, on the politics of technical expertise, and on the power that
emanates from knowledge. However, this book parts company with epistemic communities
over the key concept of normative beliefs. A subset of raters may share a
conscious commitment to such beliefs, but this commitment is a defining element
of epistemic communities. The notion of epistemic communities may be useful to
the analysis of particular elements within the rating world to be examined in
future work. An alternative concept—embedded knowledge networks—is elaborated
below.
Embedded Knowledge Networks
Embedded knowledge networks are analytical
and judgmental systems that, in principle, remain at arms length from market
transactions. "Embedded" does not mean that the networks are locked
in and, thus, simply resistant to change. "Embedded" should not
convey the idea of inertia, path dependency, or vested interests. Instead, it is
supposed to suggest that actors view embedded knowledge networks as endogenous
rather than exogenous to financial globalization. The networks are, therefore,
generally considered legitimate rather than imposed entities by market
participants.
How the networks
construct and reinforce this collective understanding of themselves is of
great interest. Where institutions that are embedded knowledge networks in one
society attempt to transplant themselves into others, they risk losing their
embedded knowledge network status, unless they recognize the necessity of
getting the market actors in these other places to recognize their endogeneity.
To return to the discussion of myth and mental frameworks, rating agencies must
adapt themselves to public expectations of what they should be doing, as they
expand from their American home base. Achieving endogeneity and, hence,
legitimacy has been easier in some places than others for the major U.S. bond
rating agencies.
The role of
knowledge in investment decision-making is at the heart of embedded knowledge
network activity. Market actors are overwhelmed with data about prices,
business activity, and political risk. A typical form of knowledge output is
some sort of recommendation, ranking, or rating, which ostensibly condenses
these forms of knowledge. This knowledge output becomes a benchmark around
which market players subsequently organize their affairs. Market actors can and
do depart from the benchmarks, but these still set the standard for the work of
other actors, providing a measure of market success or failure. In this way,
embedded knowledge network outputs play a crucial role in constructing markets
in a context of less-than- perfect information and considerable uncertainty
about the future.
Rating agencies,
acting as embedded knowledge networks, can be thought to adjust the
"ground rules" inside international capital markets, thereby shaping
the internal organization and behavior of institutions seeking funds. The
agencies' views on what is acceptable shape the actions of those seeking their
positive response. This anticipation effect or structural power is reflected in
capital market participants' understanding of the agencies' views and
expectations. In turn, this understanding acts as a base point from which
business and policy initiatives are developed. The coordination effect of
rating agencies therefore narrows the expectations of creditors and debtors to
a well-understood or transparent set of norms, shared among all parties. Thus,
the agencies do not just constrain the capital markets but actually provide
significant pressures on market participants, contributing to their internal
constitution.
Counterfactual Method
How might rationalist and constructivist
analytical lenses be deployed in this substantive discussion of rating
institutions? Since the objective is to understand the implications of the
particular rather than establish general laws, we need a suitable method of
thinking through the implications of rating. For the type of cases described in
this book, counterfactual analysis is an appropriate approach.51 In
counterfactual analysis, the factor or variable thought most likely to be
causal is subsequently excluded from an alternative scenario the researcher
constructs.52 Given this modification of what Weber terms the
"causal components," we have to think through whether, in these
changed conditions, the "same effect" would be expected empirically.53
If, in the imaginative construct established, the supposition is that the
effect would probably be different, we have likely isolated an adequate cause
in the initial scenario and can feel confident about the analysis. But, as
Weber cautions, causal significance of this sort always suggests a range of
degree of certainty about causation.54
One objection to
counterfactual scenarios is, as Ferguson notes, the notion that "there is
no limit to the number which we can consider." But the reality is quite
different. "In practice," suggests Ferguson, "there is no real
point in asking most of the possible counterfactual questions" that can be
imagined. Plausibility is key, as in all analysis. We are interested in what
happened or could have happened, not what could not have happened. Our focus
should be on "possibilities which seemed probable." Accordingly,
there is a plausible set of counterfactuals, not an infinite number of
alternatives for any situation. Even if we grant that this plausible set is
always open to critique, by requiring us to rethink our arguments, the posing
of counterfactuals is, as Ferguson suggests, a useful "antidote to
determinism."56
In the
substantive chapters of this book, a rationalist account of rating agency
effects is constrasted with a constructivist one inspired by economic
sociology. The purpose is to demonstrate the utility of a
constructivist-economic sociology analysis of rating agencies and, thus, of
IPE problems more generally. Since constructivist accounts are not always
better than rationalist ones, the working assumption is that the
constructivist-economic sociology heuristic complements the rationalist
account. In some cases, the most plausible explanation may be rationalist
rather than constructivist.
Central and Supporting Arguments
Economists have been keenly interested in
the question whether bond ratings actually add new information to markets and
thus affect market behavior. The central argument of this book concerns the
intersubjective effect of rating, that is, how rating affects the social
context in which corporate and government policy plans are made. Specific
attention is given to the power and authority of the agencies, and the
implications of rating for private and public life.
Rating agencies
are not the neutral, technical, detached, objective arbitrators they are
assumed to be among people who see them as merely transmitting market views to
investors. Capital markets (and other markets) are actually organized, coordinated,
or "made" by processes of information gathering and judgment forming
the rating agencies exemplify. These processes reflect particular ways of
thinking and reject or exclude other ways.57 The judgments produced
acquire the status of understood facts in the markets—even when analysis shows
they are at times faulty—because of the authoritative status market
participants and societies attribute to the agencies. These particular ways of
thinking, which are hegemonic in the Western world and which the agencies
enforce increasingly internationally, are referred to here as the mental
framework of rating orthodoxy.
Most broadly, it
is argued, the work of the agencies integrates further elements of economic and
political organization around the world, pushing these toward a prevailing
institutional pattern. In this emerging order, norms are increasingly shared,
and policy converges around characteristically American "best
practice."58 American ideas have become the most important
transnational ones.59 Rating agency judgments contribute to this
process, as does the work of other institutions like the IMF and World Bank.60
Three supporting
or mid-range arguments about the increasing importance of rating agency
judgments are developed.
Supporting
Argument 1: Investment
The first argument is concerned with
investment, a central feature of any modern society that produces an economic
surplus. Many economists, in the tradition of Hayek, assume that investment
happens automatically if certain basic conditions hold.61 But
investment may also be understood as an implicitly coordinated social process.
Investment has its own history and particular constraints. It is therefore
necessary to understand the context in which investment choices are made.
In current
circumstances, the increasing importance of capital markets alters the basis on
which investment is undertaken. As banks are displaced as key investment
sources, gatekeeper power is concentrated in the hands of the small number of
rating agencies. Rating judgments are more important today and this trend will
continue into the future, because less investment capital in the form of loans
is being allocated by banks. This change in the character of investment has
significant consequences for corporations and governments seeking access to
resources. Rating has become a key means of transmitting the policy orthodoxy
of managerial best practice. Much more of the world is now open to the
consequences of rating judgments than was the case during the Cold War.
Centralization
of investment judgment is the essential element of the first mid- range
argument. This argument is supported by evidence from the relationship between
corporate ratings and the cost of debt, Michael Milken's activities, and the
rating of the automobile industry. Municipal rating adds further evidence of
gatekeeping. The spread of the U.S. agencies and the emergence of local
agencies in new markets also supports this first mid-range argument.
Supporting
Argument II: Knowledge
The second argument is about knowledge.
Knowledge is usually thought of as something that transcends particular
situations or times. In fact, certain forms of knowledge are more typical of
some eras and places than others. Like the investment process, knowledge is a
social creation, an arena in which particular understandings of the world
compete for control over what is accepted as a basis for action and policy.
Politically, the key thing about knowledge is the moment when an idea changes
from being an individual idiosyncratic view to one widely or intersubjectively
held and collectively consequential. Rating judgments are not objective.
A specific form
of knowledge at the heart of the rating phenomenon has consequences for what
we think of as legitimate knowledge elsewhere in the policy process. The
knowledge form that dominates rating tends to be analytical, to focus on how
things do or should function in our world, in a cause-effect fashion. What this
analytical form excludes is an explanation of origins: how institutions develop
and also their potential for future transformation. Rating reinforces knowledge
based on the assumption of a fundamentally unchanging world, one in which economic
markets, for example, are thought to perform the same function today as
"always."
Where did this
specific form of knowledge originate? Sorel suggested the static, unhistorical
way of thinking about knowledge is a technique linked to monetary accumulation.62
It eschews reflection and puts a premium on instrumental understanding in the
here and now. Capitalism is premised on such a knowledge form. But a static
form of knowledge, under the changing conditions created by financial globalization,
makes the capacity to anticipate the events of September 11, 2001, for example,
inconceivable. Bond rating certainly did not create the static knowledge form,
but rating agencies are transmitting and reinforcing this type of knowledge
globally—with consequences for public and private policy around the world and,
therefore, the daily lives of billions.
In the corporate
world, the growth of the rating advisory industry and the rating of
telecommunication firms support these claims. Problems with quality of life
variables provide evidence from municipal rating. The creation of Japanese
rating agencies, discussed in chapter 6, also supports the claims.
Supporting
Argument III: Governance
Ironically, perhaps, rating forces change
in how we govern our lives because it spreads the static, instrumental form of
knowledge, thus challenging established ways of thinking and acting. Governance
is about how institutions or processes are organized in hierarehies and how
these structures shape our lives as citizens and consumers. Sometimes, the
existence of these governance structures is obvious, such as in the case of
representative democracy. Other governance structures are quite diffuse. They
operate in society much as operating systems do in computers, beneath the
surface of things. The third mid-range claim made in this book is that
established, historically derived norms and practices regarding governance are
challenged by the judgments of rating agencies: the views of appropriate
constitutional arrangements and corporate governance approaches that the
agencies promote are often derived from U.S. experience. Rating agencies did
not invent these governance structures but act as interpreters, advocates, and
enforcers of them around the world. When put in place, these patterns shape the
nature of working life and the limits of democracy, making the former more
insecure and competitive and the latter less inclusive and meaningful.
In chapter 4,
the problems in Japanese banks support this mid-range argument. New York City's
financial problems provide evidence from the municipal world. Additional
evidence from controversies over sovereign ratings, for both rich countries
such as Japan, Australia, and Canada, and developing countries, is given in
chapter 6.
Plan of the Book
The three supporting arguments are
developed in the chapters where the implications of rating processes in
particular contexts are investigated. First, however, in chapters 2 and 3, the
book looks at the agencies: their internal organization, important features of
their processes for creating ratings, and the relation between rating and
regulation. Next to be examined is the power and authority of rating agencies,
which underpin the mid-range issues. The key question asked is from what is
rating power derived, and what are its limits? The context is development of
the arguments about investment, knowledge, and governance to be investigated in
subsequent chapters.
In chapters 4,
5, and 6, the discussion concerns corporate rating, municipal rating, the
sovereign rating of national governments, and the growth of rating agencies
outside the United States. These accounts are organized in terms of the
arguments about investment, knowledge, and governance that are developed in
chapter 3.
This book focuses
on more than one level of analysis, such as sovereign states. The politics of
rating pervades the world order, requiring that we consider the effects on
municipal government and private corporations as well as national states. In
chapter 7, recent rating "failures" are explored. Why did these
failures happen, what marks them as failures, and to what degree have they
undermined rating authority? Just how resilient are the reputational assets the
agencies possess?
Ironically, the
financial crises of the 1990s and of the early years of the new millennium may
have actually enhanced the power of rating agencies: capital market financing
has come to be seen as less risky than traditional bank lending, especially in
emerging markets. Underlying market trends may be rescuing the rating agencies
from their critics, even as the increasing importance of rating motivates
further criticism.
The concluding
chapter examines the significance of the discussion, in particular the degree
to which authority and power take on new forms in globalized conditions and
how the agencies affect people in their everyday lives. What are some ways of
responding effectively to the heightened role of the new masters of capital?
沒有留言:
張貼留言