Public Credit and the Public Sphere
A profound crisis disrupted
the English Financial Revolution in 1710. Public credit was in a tailspin, with
government bonds trading at a heavy discount, forcing the Treasury to borrow on
increasingly unfavorable terms.1 The rapidly deteriorating trust in
public credit jeopardized the sustainability of the still developing Financial
Revolution and thus the stability of the fiscal-military state. The
crisis—called by contemporaries the “Loss of the City,—was
particularly disturbing because it revealed the extent to which public credit
was no longer an exclusive affair between the Crown and a small number of
wealthy financiers. It was now subject to the fickle judgment of the public.2
Since public debt instruments were now actively traded, the status of the
national debt was dictated by an amorphous publics decentralized judgment of
the prospects of a disembodied and depersonalized state administration. The
recognition that an intractable public opinion now dictated public credit was
deeply unsettling to traditional elites.3 While John Locke and
others had earlier argued that it was possible for people to derive
well-informed opinions that could accurately guide them in a world of
uncertainty, the consensus among philosophers was that the collective opinion
of the multitude was never accurate and therefore should not be trusted. Locke
wrote, “there cannot be a more dangerous thing to rely on, nor more likely to
mislead, one; since there is so much more Falshood and Errour amongst Men, than
Truth and Knowledge.”4
The power of public opinion to dictate public credit was seen as a
threat to the traditional political economic authority. That an anonymous public was able to influence
England s political and geopolitical options, including its
ability to wage war and thus its capacity to defend its borders and its
cherished liberties, was deeply unsettling.5 To the governing
elite, decisions about politics, war, and the succession were the sole
responsibility of people properly educated and experienced in political
affairs.6 Yet, despite their shared discomfort with the political
influence of the public, both Whigs and Tories soon realized that the
fickleness and instability of public opinion could be wielded as a political
weapon. Both parties consequently used the
public sphere to manipulate public opinion for their own ends. The incumbent
ministry tried to shape public opinion of England’s political, economic, and
military administration in order to shore up public credit, while the
opposition sought to undermine public opinion in order to sink public credit
and thus force a ministerial shift. As such, public opinion, the public sphere,
and public credit became intricately linked as the financial innovations introduced
as part of the Glorious and Financial Revolutions became permanent fixtures of
English society.7
In
exploring the politically inflected discourse on credit sparked by the 1710
crisis, I seek to address historian Mark Knights’s grievance that the early
eighteenth-century “link between opinion, credit, and partisan politics remains under-explored.”8
Not only were numerous prominent writers, such as Daniel Defoe, Jonathan Swift,
and Joseph Addison, paid to produce texts intended to shape the publics opinion
about the state of credit, but the ways in which these writers conceived and
theorized credit were deeply influenced by their party-political agendas. By
controlling the language by which the public gained financial literacy, these
writers tried to frame peoples basic understanding of what credit was and how
it worked and, in that way, to ensure that people would invest in ways that
inadvertently supported their part/s interest. In this chapter
I argue that ideas about
credit, which came to influence
the economic discourse for the rest of the century, cannot be
properly understood in isolation from the party-political wrangling of 1710.
The unprecedented spending associated with the War of Spanish Succession
(1701-1714) was primarily responsible for generating the 1710 credit crisis. But it was the intensity of the party wars between
Whigs and Tories that elevated the crisis to a national emergency. The war,
pitting England, the Dutch Republic, Austria, and Portugal against France and
Spain, was largely a continuation of the Nine Years’ War. The main strategic
aim of the Alliance was to check France’s expansion by making sure that Louis
XIVs grandson, the Duke of Anjou, was prevented from laying claim to the now
vacant Spanish throne. Instead, the Alliance supported Emperor Leopold Is son,
Charles of Austria, as the new Spanish king. If France gained control over
Spain it would then be able to take advantage of the entire Spanish empire, making
France the most powerful nation both in Europe and the Americas. The Dutch and
the English already had developed a strong imperial presence, and had even
greater aspirations, making them unwilling to stand idly by while the French
pursued their aim of universal monarchy.
England’s success in this war made it the “military Wunderkind of the age” and signaled
its emergence as a world power.9 For the first time, England was
able to mobilize a military that could rival any other European nation, in size
and firepower, both on land and at sea. During the war, England had on average
ninety-three thousand men in the army and forty-three thousand men in the navy,
compared to around twenty thousand in the army and navy respectively during the
second Anglo-Dutch war in the 1660s.10 Also contributing to
England’s success was the legendary command of John Churchill, Duke of Marlborough
(1650-1722), who skillfully managed the British redcoats and Jack Tars.11
Success, however, did not come cheaply. Maintaining armies at war in both
Flanders and Spain, as well as on the oceans, was enormously expensive. In
addition to the sheer increase in enlisted men, new types of firepower and
fortifications introduced during the seventeenth-century military revolution
added greatly to the basic expenditures of waging war.12
The expansion of England’s armed forces would not have been possible
without the Financial Revolution.13 While the Stuart monarchs had
developed a permanent Crown debt, the establishment of a perpetual public debt
with the tontine and lottery loans and the formation of the Bank of England in
the 1690s enabled the government to borrow on a greater scale and at a lower
interest than ever before.14 Hie debt was also considered more
secure now that the government had substantially improved its system of revenue
collection. In addition to the further development and use of both
indirect (excise and customs) and direct (land and hearth) taxes, the
government had also put an end to the notoriously inefficient system of tax
farming.15 A relatively efficient corps of civil servants was now in
charge of the collection of taxes.16 Collectively, these fiscal
reforms enabled the Treasury to raise more money faster and the state to carry
a much greater debt burden, contributing substantially to England’s financial
flexibility.17
In the political realm, the already sharp hostility between Whigs
and Tories intensified. The two parties had originated during the Exclusion
Crisis of the 1670s over the issue of whether a Catholic monarch, in this case
Duke of York, should be allowed to succeed to the throne. The two-party system
emerged in an even more prominent role when Parliaments authority was enhanced
as a result of the financial settlement of the Glorious Revolution and the
passing of the Triennial Act in 1694. Debates on controversial issues like
religion, foreign policy, military strategy, and public finance were
increasingly staged within this binary opposition, the vehemence of which
occasionally conjured up fears of another civil war.18 While the
electorate decided on the composition of the House of Commons, the monarch
selected the ministry. Since the ministry had to work closely with the Commons,
which now controlled the fiscal machinery, the monarch’s choice was
circumscribed by political pragmatism. The Whigs were generally better
organized than the Tories. The so-called Whig Junto successfully coordinated
and managed the party so that even though the Tories won four out of five elections
during Anne’s reign, the Whigs maintained significant influence.19
In general, Anne tried to select political moderates for her ministry to ensure
that the party conflict did not cripple the political administration. This led
to her selection of Sir Sidney Godolphin (1645-1712) as Lord Treasurer in 1702,
who together with Marlborough successfully governed the country for the next
eight years.20 While both of them started out as moderate Tories,
they soon became allied with the Whig Junto, as they found the Whigs more
supportive of the war effort.
The debate on public credit was mostly conducted along party
lines. Although actually composed of numerous layers of complex ideological
conflict, the Whig-Tory opposition generally mapped well onto the divide
between the landed and moneyed interests.21 While the Tory landed
interest included some traditionalists who advocated a mostly agrarian-based civic
republican society, free from a standing army, national debt, and moneyed men,
most of the landed men had by this time become favorably inclined towards
commercially oriented agriculture, wide-reaching domestic markets, and active
colonial expansion.22 Moreover, they were increasingly accepting of
the new financial configuration or at least certain parts of it.23
As long as a Tory-friendly alternative to the Whig Bank of England was
implemented and the recent increases in the land tax used to service the states
deficits were rolled back, the landed interest seemed to have transcended its
aversion to elaborate financial schemes.24 The landed interest had
been trying for some time to establish a land bank, but the failure of John
Asgills and Nicholas Barbons project in 1695 had forced them to look for other
solutions compatible with their political and economic interests. They now
concentrated on establishing a joint-stock company with the capacity to lend to
the government on the same scale as the Bank of England and the East India
Company, hoping that such large-scale lending would earn the Tories greater
leverage over public policy.25
The moneyed interest was comprised mostly of merchants, bankers,
and financiers. Often viewed as arrivistes or parvenus, Whig merchants and financiers often had landed
roots. While they could not rival the accumulated wealth of landed men, their
rapid commercial gains and the liquidity of their wealth was nevertheless
intimidating to traditional elites. The moneyed interests were in general
supportive of commercial and financial undertakings. Some preferred particular
types of commerce, for example, domestic industry over the reexport trade,
while others valorized trade over finance, in particular speculation and
stockjobbing. Most were pleased with recent political and financial
transformations and viewed the Glorious Revolution and the formation of the
Bank of England as conducive to their aims. Predictably, they were also
supportive of the shift from a heavy reliance on the hearth tax to the land tax
to finance the wars. Because of the lucrative lending opportunities the war
provided, many of the moneyed men believed that it was worthwhile to continue
fighting until the French were definitively defeated and English merchants were
in a position to take over the bulk of French colonial commerce.26
For much of the War of Spanish Succession, the Godolphin-
Marlborough ministry enjoyed great military and political success. It
transformed what had initially been a defensive military strategy into one in
which Britain scored a number of decisive victories that significantly changed
the European balance of power. This accomplishment was made even more
impressive by the fact that it was achieved without bankrupting the nation. In
fact, the ministry harnessed the nations resources in a way that left state
finances in better shape than they had been during the previous war and, more
importantly, in better shape than those of its enemy.27 By 1709,
however, England’s string of military successes were replaced by a failed peace
at The
Hague and a bloody battle at Malpla- quet, and the escalating expenses of the
war had pushed the nascent fiscal apparatus to its limits. With spending
averaging £7 million per year, the total public debt had skyrocketed from £14
million to £36 million during the course of the war.28 Short-term
military departmental debts had begun to spiral out of control, with the navy,
army, ordnance, and transportation debentures—most of which were short-term
loans unsecured by specific revenue flows—trading at an alarming discount.29
The largest component, the navy bonds, traded at a 35 percent discount in 1710
and the army and transport debentures reached a 40 percent discount in the
beginning of 1711, signaling the publics eroding confidence in the governments
capacity to adequately service its debts.30 In addition, Exchequer
Bills, considered the most secure financial instruments at the time, with
liquidity almost as high as coin itself, had also begun to drop below par. To
darken the economic horizon further, there was a general disruption in European
financial markets and a string of failed insurance companies that centered on
London.31
Also contributing to the political crisis of the ministry in 1710
was the Sacheverell affair. The Reverend Dr. Henry Sacheverell (d. 1724),a High Church clergyman, used the pulpit to question the
legitimacy of the political order established by the Glorious Revolution. His
sermons were attended by large crowds and printed versions sold more than one
hundred thousand copies, igniting an intense public debate about the present
division of power between Parliament and the Crown. To discredit the Tory
attacks, the Whigs decided to impeach Sacheverell before the House of Lords.
But instead of gaining public support, the trial generated widespread support
for Sacheverell and the Tory cause.32 In the rioting that followed,
angry mobs attacked dissenters’ meetinghouses, as well as the Bank of England,
which constituted a powerful symbol of the new political order.33
The sermons, trial, riots, and surrounding debates generated an adverse
political climate for the ministry, at the same time that it galvanized the
Tory party.
Further political controversy was stirred up by the ministry’s
failure to secure an honorable peace with France. The Tories blamed the Whigs
for intentionally making excessive demands on the French in order to ensure
that the war was prolonged and that the moneyed interest could continue
benefiting from lending to the government. The landed interest was
understandably troubled, considering that taxes on their land paid for much of
the war and thus also served to enrich the bondholders.34 The
political and financial climate in England during the summer of 1710 pointed
towards a serious crisis for the ministry.
The political turmoil reached a crescendo in June of 1710, when
the queen dismissed the Earl of Sunderland, Marlborough s son-in- law, from the
office of secretary of state and replaced him with a Tory. Sensing that even
more radical changes were underway, the Whigs embarked on a campaign to
convince the queen that an overhaul of the ministry would have disastrous
consequences, in particular for public credit. The prominent merchant and
director of the Bank of England, Sir Gilbert Heathcote (1652-1733), who
staunchly supported the Whig battle cry of “No Peace without Spain,” wielded
his political clout to help the Godolphin ministry weather the storm. On the
day after Sunderland s dismissal, Heathcote paid the queen a visit to obtain an
assurance that no further political changes were pending. The resulting
commitment by the queen was of course nothing more than a stalling tactic to
keep the channels of credit from the Bank open, if only until the more radical
changes were unveiled. In addition, her former advisor and confidant, Sarah
Churchill (1660-1744), the Duchess of Marlborough, sent the queen a warning of
the financial implications of a ministerial change: “I may tell your Majesty
what I have lately heard for the honour of my Lord Treasurer [Godolphin] from
all the considerable men in the city, which is, that if he should be removed,
they would not lend a farthing of money.”35 The queen had now been
duly warned that any further political reforms would occasion a “Loss of the
City•”
The final undoing of Godolphin came in
August. When the Bank was asked by the military pay offices to discount a
number of bills of exchange — normally
a routine line of short-term credit that the Bank provided to the Treasury — the Bank declined on the basis that it could not afford to take on
such risks in the midst of political instability and sinking credit. Heathcote
told Godolphin that the Bank now needed an assurance in writing from the queen
that no further ministerial changes were forthcoming. This move turned out to
be a serious miscalculation and on August 8, 1710, the queen
dismissed Godolphin. Two days later she announced Robrt Harley as the new Chancellor of the Exchequer,
effectively making him the new first minister.36
England was now in a state of political and financial crisis. What
would the consequences of this ministerial change be on domestic politics and
how would this alter England’s approach to the war? How would financial markets
react to the turbulence? Would a ministry favoring the landed interests honor
the governments outstanding debts to the commercial and moneyed interests?
Worst of all, the Whigs warned, would an impoverished English military have to
capitulate to its longtime enemy and face a French invasion with its resulting
absolutism and papal tyranny? While all of these concerns were foisted on
Harley from the very beginning of his tenure, the most immediate challenge he
faced was to find a way to shore up public credit. Tlie future of Harleys
ministry, the stability of the fiscal-military state, the continuity of the
financial apparatus, and indeed the security of England relied on a rapid
solution to the crisis of public credit.
Harley
promptly went to work to raise enough funds to keep credit afloat and the armed
forces at war. Contrary to the advice from some of the more radical Tories who
tried to convince him to rely solely on money from the landed interests, he
wisely did not give up on courting the Whig moneyed interest. Although the
Bank of England did not grant him all the funds he requested on the terms he
had hoped for, the fact that they were willing to extend any loans at all sent
important signals that the established channels of government finance were
still open.37 Encouraged by their success in managing the reaction
to the ministerial change, the new ministry and the queen launched the next
phase of their political agenda and dissolved the Whig-dominated Parliament at
the end of September; a new election was called for October. This brought
about a sell-off of government bonds and stocks in the Bank of England and East
India Company, causing prices to fall and nervous foreign investors to withdraw
funds and smuggle specie abroad, noticeably reducing the circulation of coin in
England. While the ministry and the queen repeatedly tried to reassure the city
that they were committed to political and religious moderation, and that they
would do everything in their power to uphold public credit, fears that the
ministry would default on — or
use a sponge to
wipe out — the entire national debt kept on escalated, thus contributing to
the severity of the financial crisis.
The crisis of 1710 sparked a vigorous debate about the nature of
credit and the most appropriate way to restore it to its former glory. It was
clear to all observers that the transformation of public credit during the
Financial Revolution had significantly altered the composition of both
creditors and debtors. Hie institutionalization and bureaucratization of the
state, combined with the increased transferability of government bonds,
generated an increasingly anonymous and detached relationship between the two
poles of the credit relationship. Since the state no longer raised money on the
personal reputation of the monarch and his connections to specific goldsmith
bankers, tax-farmers, landed men, and wealthy merchants, but rather on the
investing publics opinion of the effectiveness of the states management of the
fiscal apparatus, the state-as-public-debtor became more abstract and
disembodied.38 At the same time, lending to the government no longer
locked creditors into a longterm personal relationship with the state. The
increased transferability of government securities and the resulting market in
these instruments enabled government creditors to unload their financial assets
whenever their opinion of the investment changed.39 Public credit
thus came to depend on how public opinion perceived the states current capacity
to service the interest payments and its imaginary ability to repay the debt in
some distant, theoretical future.40 In this new culture of credit,
public opinion became the arbiter of public credit, dictating everything from
England's imperial campaigns, fiscal administration, and legislative decisions
to the choice of ministers.41
The number of people who translated public opinion into a rising
or falling credit by trading bonds was rapidly expanding, reaching approximately
eleven thousand in 1710 and close to forty thousand a decade later.42
The vast majority of these investors held only a small number of bonds and the
practice of joint, multiple, and corporate holdings of securities was rare.43
This made it unlikely that any person or body had the capacity to consistently
exert influence over financial markets.44 The majority of the
investors were metropolitan British merchants, along with significant numbers
of French,
Dutch, Huguenot, and Jewish investors. Women also played a major
role: alongside wealthy merchants, peers, gentry, civil servants, and
professional men, rich widows were counted among the major proprietors of
financial assets.45 The middling sorts came into contact with the
new financial instruments as well, attracted by the mounting spirit of
investment, speculation, and gambling.46 Even people of more modest
means invested in financial markets by buying a share — one-tenth or one-twentieth — of a £10 lottery loan ticket. Opportunities to invest in these
securities were plentiful, as the government issued more than half a million
£10 tickets and thirty thousand £100 tickets between 1711 and 1714, sold partly
in well-frequented pubs.47 With aspirations of winning the grand
prize, thousands of investors showed up at Guildhall for the public drawings,
turning these events into major public spectacles, which William Hogarth would
later satirize in his painting The Lottery (1724).
The investing public thus constituted a remarkably large and
diverse body of people.48 And, these investors channeled the opinion
of an even wider non-investing public. Since the issues pertaining to public
credit were deeply intertwined with other major issues of the day — party politics, foreign policy, the succession, and religious
controversy — the opinion of the investing public was formed within a much
broader public sphere, informing many tens, if not hundreds, of thousands of
people. This public significantly overlapped with the parliamentary electorate — consisting of an estimated three hundred thousand men at this
point—but arguably represented a broader and more diverse political force.49
The fact that public opinion was based on the beliefs and
sentiments of such a decentered and fragmented public made it almost impossible
to control. Propagandists nevertheless tried to access this public and
influence its thinking by flooding the public sphere with their writings.50
In so doing, they took advantage of an already vibrant print culture that had
developed as a result of increasing literacy rates, a burgeoning commerce in
cheap print, frequent electioneering, an expansion in the number of public
petitions, and the lapse of the Licensing Act in 1695.51 Hiis
flourishing print culture was particularly useful to political challengers,
who were now able to orchestrate elaborate campaigns against incumbents.52
However, the reigning ministry, although often forced to defend itself against
its critics, also used the public sphere to try to shape public opinion.
Experimenting with different mediums and messages, and widely
disseminating their publications, propaganda writers primarily targeted people
operating in urban public spaces like pleasure gardens, the Royal Exchange,
Exchange Alley, alehouses, and coffeehouses. Providing access to people of
most social groups, political leanings, economic standing, and religious
convictions, London’s approximately five hundred coffeehouses played a
particularly important role as spaces in which public opinion was formed. And,
since much of the trade in stocks and bonds was carried out in coffeehouses
located in Exchange Alley, in particular Jonathan’s and Garraways, changes in
public opinion informed by coffeehouse conversations often translated immediately
into rising or falling credit. The spatial and conceptual proximity between
Exchange Alley and the coffeehouse thus ensured that the public sphere and the
new system of public credit mutually conditioned each other during the
Financial Revolution.53 Hence, the public sphere not only promoted a
more democratic political discourse, as the philosopher Jurgen Habermas
famously proposed, it also contributed to the democratization of public credit.54
Yet, it should be noted that the public sphere informing decisions
regarding public credit at the turn of the eighteenth century differed in
important ways from that theorized by Habermas.55 The seventeenth-
century English version of the public sphere was not exclusively a space for
rational public criticism of the state. Instead, the ministry was trying to
shape public opinion as much as was the opposition, making the public sphere a
forum for debate between multiple oppositional forces and the state, rather
than solely an avenue for criticism of the state.56 Furthermore, the
conversation about public credit was not exclusively based on rational critical
arguments, in which equal individuals recognized “the better argument.”57
Instead, since the debate was designed to sway the public’s sentiment,
imagination, or expectations, rational arguments were not always preferred.
Instead, propaganda writers used multiple types of arguments, rhetoric, and
evidence, the epistemic content of which occasionally promoted rational
discourse, while oftentimes relying instead on satire, humor, distraction, and
obfuscation.58
The
fact that these debates were conducted in multiple types of media, including
newsprint, pamphlets, broadsides, and ballads, raises the question of whether
it might be more accurate to think in terms of multiple separate and partially
overlapping public spheres, rather than one larger public sphere.59 The Whig
historian lohn Gldmixon, for example, argued in l714 that the content and
audience of different forms of propaganda yielded radically different
reactions. “Parnphlets work slowly,” he Wrote, “and the Operation of one
Pamphlet is often spoil’d by that of another,” while the “Crying and Singing”
of the balladeers “warms the Minds of the Rabble, who are more capable of
Action than Speculation.”60 Although all spaces for public discussion were not
open to every person and all publications were not intended for every audience,
the fact that pamphlets, newspapers, and ballads tended to share the same
general concerns meant that even disjointed social groups were exposed to
largely the same set of ideas and arguments. Since similar conversations were
carried 0n in many different spheres, it therefore seems plausible to think in
terms of one diverse, yet uniñed, public sphere. In fact, it was this
heterogeneity and amor» phousness ofthe public sphere that intrigued and
threatened contempGraries. To them, the public exercised a palpable political
force, yet it was impossible to pinpoint its exact social location. Hence, by
trying to disaggregate the public sphere and pin down its specific location
there is a risk of losing the very quality that linked public opinion to the
views of the multitude and thus made it such an enigmatic and intimidating
social phenomenon to those who tried to manage it.
The fluidity, elasticity, and open-endedness of opinion allowed
for the simultaneous presence of different, often conflicting, public opin~
ions. 'lhat is, contrary to the singularity and coherence that Habermas argues
public opinion developed later in the eighteenth century, public opinion did
not denote a general agreement at this point, but rather represented a
multiplicity of opinions, ranging from different nuances of the same general
idea to diametrically opposing views.61 "Ihe very fact that public opinion
was not ñrrnly grounded in reason or a careful empirical assessment meant that
it also had the capacity to change suddenly and with little warning, In the
midst of this general fear ofthe precariousness of opinion, Whig and Tory
writers sought to exploit this ñckleness to further their respective political
agendas.
Propaganda and the Shaping
of Public Opinion
Party politics informed every
facet of the debate on credit. As Mark Knights points out, partisanship
“ensured that everything political could
be seen in two ways-the same words, phrases, people, and events were routinely
represented differently according to party allegiance.”62 The challenge for
propagandists was therefore to construct a convincing theory, or narrative,
that enabled people to comprehend the world from a particular point of View. As
Knights notes, the “political struggle was thus a competition between and over
rival representations and truth-claims.”63 In the realm of finance, the
challenge was to shape people’s economic literacy and their understanding ofthe
present financial crisis, partly so that they would invest in ways that
promoted the party cause. 'Iliat is, both Whig and Tory writers oifered
theories and analyses aimed at improving financial conditions, at the same time
that they sought to promote their party’s political interests.
The Whig position on public credit was most clearly articulated by
the prolific propagandist Benjamin Hoadly (1676-1761).64 Writing at the time of
Godolphins dismissal, he warned ofthe multiple disasters that a ministerial and
parliamentary rearrangement would bring about. Adopting the voice of a Tory who
recognized the damages his party was inflicting on the nation, in his Thoughts
of an Honest Tory (1710) Hoadly warned against the sinister aims of Tory
politicians. His fictitious persona claimed he had always supported the Tories
and Worked for a Tory majority, but that now he was “quite sick at the review
ofthe Methods our Friends have used to gain this happy Prospect.”65 Warning
that a continuation of party conflict was jeopardizing the status of pub~ lic
credit at a particularly inopportune moment, he queried ominously:
Is
this a time for such a Total Alternation [in the ministry], as must shake the
confidence of Friends, and inspire the Enemy with Hopes? Is this the Season for
an entire change of Hands, when Publiek Credit must be sunk into nothing,
before the rest of Europe can have time to know whom they are to depend upon,
and the people at home Whom they are to trust? 66
A
political rearrangement would completely undermine public credit and would thus
force England to accept an inglorious peace with France and a return of the
Pretender-lames II’s son )ames Francis Stuartwho had already made an attempt to
invade England in 1708. And, if the present party hostilities were not quickly
brought under control, noth~ ing prevented that “the field of Election should
become a ßeld ofBattle.”67
The potentially disastrous
consequence of an implosion of public credit continued to be Hoadly’s main
theme in Fears and Sentiments
of all True Britains; With Respect to National Credit, Interest and
Religion (1710). Instead of using the rhetorical
technique of impersonating his opponents, he now pretended to tone down the
partisan tenor by defending the interests of all Englishmen, another common
literary device. In exploring the nature of credit and its importance to
England's power and prosperity, he sought to form a better understanding of how
credit crises occured and what could be done to prevent them in the future.
Like many of his contemporaries, Hoadly located the essence of credit in trust.
He argued that one of the most essential components of trust is the borrower’s
reputation for prudence, which can only be built up over time. “Publick Credit,” he wrote, is “like Private Reputation; obtained by a Series of good Conduct made up of a multitude of good Actions.”68 The
splendid reputation that Godolphin had built up over the years thus constituted
an indispensable asset to the state. But now that he had been dismissed, trust
had to be rebuilt from scratch.
Hoadly highlighted that the past was not the only component that
dictated trust. Expectations of the future and imaginations of the unknown were
at least as important in deciding the status of credit. This is exactly what
made credit such an enigmatic and unpredictable phenomenon. Since expectations
and the imagination could never be firmly grounded in certainty or controlled
by authority, Hoadly noted that a certain anxiety inevitably accompanied
credit. Credit’s capacity to transfer the implications of an event through
space and time and to generate real implications of an imagined event meant
that the mere suspicion of an unfavorable future or distant event had the
capacity to become a serious threat to credit in the present. For Hoadly, the
current prospects of a dissolution of Parliament exemplified how such “an ugly
fear” of the future might cause public credit to sink in the present.69
Because of its sensitivity to speculations about the future,
credit was particularly vulnerable to the ongoing party strife. Hoadly consequently
lambasted the Tories for jeopardizing public credit by ceaselessly scheming
for their own political advantage. He accused them of opportunistically putting
their own fortunes ahead of the national interest. He called for a greater
sense of mutual responsibility among the feuding political actors in order to
stabilize credit and thus secure the continuity of the political order created
by the Glorious Revolution. While political parties should be allowed to freely
squabble over most things, they should resolve to treat public credit as a
national concern, transcending the pettiness of party politicking.70
The Tories ought to realize, he wrote, that a fall in public credit would
severely damage England’s national security. A falling credit would not only
weaken the nation in itself, it would also worsen England’s relative position
as England's loss of credit would be Frances gain. He wrote, “as the first
raising our Credit to such a pitch, was the Entire
ruine of the French Kings Credit;
so the Death of ours must necessarily give a New Life to hisP1 The only reasonable solution to the present problem, therefore,
was to invite Godolphin back to once again manage public credit.
Hoadly ended his pamphlet by reminding the Tory landed interest
that in the event that the October elections granted them a parliamentary
majority, they ought to prudently manage the national debt. He suggested that
they should refrain from mismanaging or defaulting on the national debt, ultimately
in order to protect their own wealth. Because if the government were to default
on its debt and thus erase the property of the moneyed interest, there should
never be any surety in the minds of the landed interest that the government
would not, at some point, seize their lands and estates as well. In that
circumstance, he asked, “What can be secure? What can be a Titley or a Right? Or, what can become of Property?”72 In
Hoadly s mind, even though financial wealth was grounded in immaterial and
abstract future-oriented notions—like trust, confidence, and opinion—it
nevertheless carried the same legitimacy as the most real and concrete forms of
property. Consequently, Hoadly argued, if financial property were violated it
would constitute a full-on attack on the long-celebrated English ideals of
property and liberty, and would thus undermine the very foundation of society.73
Hoadly s Whig intervention was quickly challenged by the Tories.
The new Lord Treasurer Robert Harley assembled an impressive propaganda team,
including Simon Clement (1654-1730), Abel Boyer (1667- 1729),Jonathan Swift (1667-1745), and Daniel Defoe (1660-1731).74
Once in control of the ministry, Harley and the Tories were intent on managing
expectations and imaginations in a manner that kept public credit afloat. With
the help of these writers, Harley sought to establish a uniquely Tory
understanding of the nascent culture of credit. Written under the direct
supervision of Harley himself, Clements Faults on
Both Sides: Or, An Essay upon the Original Cause, Progress, and Misch- evious
Consequences of the Factions in this Nation
(1710) commented
on recent English political history through the lens of the
Whig-Tory divide.75 His historical analysis culminated in a
discussion of the contemporary challenges facing England, including a
point-by-point refutation of Hoadly.
Clement had much to say on the issue of credit, offering the
Tories both a different analysis of the financial crisis and a different way of
assessing the imaginary component of credit. First, he criticized the directors
of the Bank of England for interfering with the queens choice of ministers and
thus acquiescing to becoming an instrument of party. While his criticism of the
Whig Bank was harshly worded, he took great pains to flatter and praise
individual directors of the Bank, most likely to avoid jeopardizing Harleys
continued relationship with them. Clement also addressed the threat of a “Loss
of the City,” or that “this change of the Ministers will fall the Stocks, Foreigners
will draw their Money out of our publick Funds, and both publick and private
Credit will be ruin’d.”76 To Clement, these scenarios were mere
fabrications and empty speculations designed to “frighten ignorant and
unthinking People.”77 He nevertheless spent a great deal of effort
trying to dispel the fears of such a loss.
On the issue of falling securities prices, Clement offered a
different interpretation of how public opinion influences credit. While Hoadly
argued that expectations and imagination formed by the public were unavoidable
and integral to the determination of securities prices, Clement claimed that
the only true measure of a stock s value was its intrinsic worth, which was
determined by the size of the company s capital stock, the performance of its
managers, and its recent profits and losses. Similarly, the price of government
bonds ought to be dictated by the revenues of the state, the character of the
fiscal managers, and the recent history of the debt. The key ingredients in the
formation of trust, according to Clement, were thus transparency, managers
with reputations for integrity and propriety, and financial instruments backed
by impeccable security. Apart from making the manipulation of credit a capital
offense, he highlighted the very same ingredients of trust that earlier
writers, discussed in Chapter 3,had posited.
If stock or bond prices would increase beyond that which the fundamentals
dictated, it could only be attributed to an increase in what Clement called “imaginary wealth!778 By
portraying the value generated by a favorable public opinion as fictitious,
unreal, or imaginary, Clement
dismissed the publics newfound capacity to dictate credit as
largely irrelevant and irrational. That is, public opinion was not the expression
of the general populations careful assessment, but rather a confused,
uninformed, and unfounded sense that must be acknowledged as such. Moreover, he
blamed the most recent run-up of the “imaginary value” on the sordid dealings
of the stockjobbers, a group that had long been vilified for their
contributions to the destabilization of credit.79 He consequently
regarded the fall in stock and bond prices after the ousting of Godolphin as an
inconsequential adjustment in the publics imagination or opinion, unworthy of
serious attention.
The difference between Hoadly,s
and Clements understandings of credit captures an important tension between the
Whig proponents of the new financial system and the more conservative landed
Tory tradition. For Clement, the intrinsic value is the “true” value, while
the “imaginary value” is based on unsubstantiated beliefs and conjectures. Hie
latter is seen as dangerously precarious in that it is liable to speculation,
rumors, manipulations, and lies. Every investor knew and tacitly accepted that
credit was inherently risky and uncertain. However, as Locke and others had
already explored, it was nevertheless possible to form a sound opinion that a
person could trust.80 The key was for every person to remain
informed of the relevant conditions and only trust the most skilled witnesses.81
But this was hardly the case in reality, Clement and the Tories insisted. In
practice, most people based their opinion on what the multitude believed, which
meant that opinion did not approximate true knowledge and therefore did not
serve as a reliable guide for action. Clement thus viewed the abstract and
immaterial component of financial assets with much greater suspicion than
Hoadly. The Tories were consequently much more comfortable, at least for the
moment, with real existing assets, like land and merchandise, serving as
security for financial assets. Hoadly, on the other hand, while also recognizing
the precariousness of public opinion, did not ascribe any particular normative
qualities to opinion and expectations, viewing them instead as natural and
unavoidable features of all credit instruments.
Lurking beneath the surface of this debate about expectations and
opinion was a deeper controversy over political and economic authority. Was
society still under the rational, skillful, and just leadership of the landed
elites or had the commercial and moneyed interests acquired a greater political
influence through the public debt? Even worse, was it possible that no one was
really in clear control of the economy and that it was now dictated by an
amorphous and anarchic public opinion? The commonplace concern among the landed
interest that the expansion of public credit would introduce rampant
speculation and corruption had now been augmented by the fear that important
political and economic decisions were dictated by people who did not even
understand what the impact of their actions would be on England’s political and
geopolitical future.
Clements intervention generated a series of Whig responses, including
Joseph Trapps Most Faults on One
Side (1710), an anonymous authors Faults in
the Fault-Finder (1710) and A Supplement to Faults in the Fault-Finder (1711),and a series of articles by
Arthur Maynwar- ing (1668-1712) in the Whig newspaper The Medley. To address these, Clement
wrote a rejoinder titled A Vindication of the
Faults on Both Sides (1710), in which he further
explored the issue of public credit He once again revealed his discomfort with
credit’s dependency on expectations, opinion, and imagination. To combat this
inherent fickleness, he reiterated the importance of good securities backing
debt instruments and transparent bookkeeping so that security prices
accurately reflected existing conditions.82 In addition to his
discussion of the importance of prudence and probity in issuing debt
instruments, he restated his views on the distinction between intrinsic and
imaginary value. He advised that “People ought never to value them [stocks] by
the Rates they may go at in Exchange-Alfy, but to inform themselves truly of the certain Sum that has been
paid into the Stock, and of the Dividend that is constantly made, together
with the probable Success of the Management.”83 Clement thus
suggested that the best way to manage the imaginary component was to devalue
its importance so that people would simply ignore it. People should look at the
empirical facts, not follow the confusion generated by rumors, propaganda, and
lies.
Sensing that a massive propaganda campaign would be necessary for
his ministry to sway public opinion, Harley employed the prolific writer Abel
Boyer to write for his cause.84 Boyer had collaborated with Harley
in the past, but it was only in the autumn of 1710 that Harley invited him to o伍dally produce propaganda in his service. In An Essay towards the History of the Last Ministry and Parliament (1710), Boyer laid out a series of arguments designed to
influence the publics opinion of Harleys stewardship of the government and thus
their assessment of public credit. In building his case, Boyer explored the
centrality of credit to the modern state and economy. Without credit, he
argued, only a fraction of desired commercial transactions would be carried out
and the state would find itself unable to fulfill its most basic responsibilities.
As such, “Credit is become the very Heart and Soul of all Trade and Commerce, either private or publick,5 In fact, public credit had
become so important, he argued, that any activity that threatened to undermine
it should be considered high treason.
In order to pinpoint its essential workings, Boyer sketched a rudimentary
definition of credit. He claimed that credit is “The Opinion or Confidence we have in another s Ability, Honour, and Punctuality to Discharge
or Pay a Debt”86 Public credit, by
extension, is “the same Opinion or Confidence, with respect to the State or Government, founded on the
Experience of its Ability, Honesty, and Punctuality.”87 Boyer recognized that a mix of reputation and expectation
dictated the status of credit. However, uncomfortable with the role played by
public opinion as the arbiter of credit, he tried, like Clement, to make credit
more stable by grounding it in something less precarious and ephemeral. Similar
to many of the seventeenth-century political economic writers, Boyer proposed
that if the managers of public credit were men of impeccable honor and
character, as well as sufficient means, their ingrained moral virtues might
stabilize public opinion and therefore infuse credit with a greater sense of
surety and constancy. This argument was pleasing to the landed interest, who
believed that their pedigree and socialization made them uniquely suited and
equipped for political authority. Because, according to Boyer, such men had
England s long-term interest in mind, they would not succumb to the same
temptations as the profit-thirsty moneyed classes, which meant that the
financial system would be placed on a firmer footing.
Boyer moreover refuted Hoadly s claim that the elimination of
Godolphin had caused credit to collapse. He developed an argument to show that
public credit never depends on one person alone and that the dismissal of
Godolphin in favor of Harley could not have been the cause of credit’s
collapse.88 Does the publics confidence, he asked, reside in the
state administration, or with the specific individuals in charge of managing
the fiscal apparatus? On the most basic level, he argued, opinion about the
state’s capacity to service its debt should be dictated by the wealth of the nation
and Parliament’s ability and willingness to channel
this wealth towards the public debt. This suggested to Boyer that
public credit depends firstly on Parliament, as this body was responsible for
the requisitioning of funds to service the debt, and secondarily on the queen,
as she was responsible for selecting “Able, Honest, and Faithful Officers in
the Government of the Treasury and Exchequer.,,89 No particular public
official was therefore responsible for public credit, which meant that credit
ought not to sink as a result of a ministerial change.
Boyer was trying to come to grips with the depersonalization of
public credit created by the disembodiment of the state and the increased
transferability of government bonds. He challenged the Whig position, earlier
articulated by Hoadly, that since public credit is “like Private Reputation,^ and since Godolphin
had already established himself as having an impeccable integrity, he should be
allowed to continue serving as Lord Treasurer.90 Instead of recognizing
that the monarch no longer was the main symbol and guarantor of the states
credibility and that public credit consequently had become depersonalized,
Hoadly claimed that the Lord Treasurer had replaced the monarch as the personal
guarantor of the states credit. Boyer, on the other hand, argued that the
traditional notion of public credit as lodged in the monarch’s— or any other
public persons—reputation no longer captured the realities of public credit.
The state administrators’ honor, probity, and respectability were still of
utmost importance to the formation of trust, but it did not matter who
specifically served in these positions of power. For the public to be able to
trust, public credit had to be managed by men of virtue. Virtue was thus not removed
from the concept of credit, but it was powerfully depersonalized.
Even though Boyer showed that public credit does not rely on any
particular person, the fact that the price of government securities had indeed
fallen in the immediate aftermath of Godolphins dismissal required Boyer to
provide an alternative explanation. He argued that part of the reason was that
Godolphin had run up such a staggering debt, making people doubt whether it
could be adequately serviced. He also suggested that the Exchequer had
mismanaged the collection of taxes, that England’s foreign trade was
overburdened by excessive duties, and that a negligent colonial administration
had squandered lucrative trading opportunities. However, the primary reason for
the fall in public credit was the precariousness and fickleness inherent in
public opinion. He remarked that even though the fiscal apparatus
Public Credit and the Public Sphere 181
Was impeccably organized and the new Treasury oflîcers were indeed
honest, able, and punctual, what mattered most was “the Opinion or Confidence,
we have that they are really Honest, Able, and Punctual.”91 This led Boyer to
conclude that “the Excellency of Credit rests on a slippery Bottom, I mean,
OPINION; which being Nice, Tender, and easily Affected and Byass’d, so Credit
either rises or falls with it.”92 Boyer here echoes Charles Davenant’s famous
reflection on the irrationality of public opinion and the threat to political
stability that it constituted. Boyer, however, believed that this was just a
momentary instability and that once Harley and his administration were given a
chance to prove themselves, public opinion would turn in their favor and credit
would soon rise again. rIhat is, as long as people focused on the soundness of
the security of ñnancial assets and the integrity of the managers, public
opinion did not have to be destabilizing.
rlhe writer who would end up playing the most active and arguably
most effective role in Harley’s propaganda machinery was Daniel Defoe.93 Defoe
had previously written for Harley when he was a member of the Godolphin
ministry, but when Harley was dismissed from the ministry in 1708, Defoe stayed
on and continued Working for him until the fall ofthe Whig Iunto was imminent.
On Iuly 17, 1710, Defoe wrote to Harley asking him to renew his patronage. He
proclaimed that “It would be a Double honour to Me to have my Gratitude Mixt
with the Service of My Country.”94 Harley Was naturally delighted to add such a
prolific pen to his cause. After a couple of months of guarded or tepid
support, Defoe’s triweekly Review ofthe State of the British Nation took on an
increasingly Harleyian bias, and after another few months Defoe began producing
pamphlets in explicit support of Harley’s ideas and policies.
In
August of 1710, the same month in which Queen Anne replaced Godolphin with
Harley, Defoe published An Essay upon Publiek Credit, one of the period’s most
intriguing reflections on credit.95 While the central aim of this essay was to
show, similar to Boyer, that public credit was never lodged in one person
alone, the most fascinating feature of this pamphlet was Defoes recognition of the
difficulties of grasping the essence of credit.96 He announced at the outset:
I am to speak of what all People are busie about,
but not one in Forty understands: Every Man has a Concern in it, few know what
it is, nor is it easy to define or describe it. If
a Man goes about to explain it by Words, he rather struggles to lose himself in the Wood, than bring
others
out of it. It is best described by it self; 5tis like the
Wind that blows where it lists,
we hear the sound thereof, but hardly know whence it come,
or whither it goes.97
For Defoe, credit was
a deeply mysterious phenomenon, the ontology of which could not be determined
analytically. While credit is clearly recognizable when it makes its
appearance, it is near impossible to completely articulate exactly where it
comes from and how it can exist. Defoe continued in the same spirit, “Like the Soul in the Body, it acts all
Substance, yet is it self Immaterial; it gives Motion, yet it self cannot be
said to Exist; it creates Forms, yet has it self no Form; it
is neither Quantity or Quality; it has no Whereness, or Whenness, Scite, or Habit,8 Defoe offered a similarly
ambivalent reflection on credit in his Review. He wrote:
Credit, seems to have a distinct Essence (if nothing can be said to exist)
from all the Phaenomena in Nature: it is in it self the lightest
and most volatile Body in the World, moveable beyond the Swiftness of
Lightning; the greatest Alchymist could never fix its Mercury, or find out its
Quality; it is neither a Soul or a Body; it is neither visible or invisible;...
A perfect free Agent acting by Wheels and Springs absolutely undiscovered.99
Given these qualities, Defoe resorted to a more pragmatic
understanding based on the ways that credit had functioned in practice.
Defoe
explored the roots of the English credit system, tracing it back to the
scarcity of money that resulted from the rapid expansion of world commerce in
the sixteenth century. Because the world supply of gold and silver was relatively
fixed, when trade steadily increased there came a point when all desired
transactions could no longer be undertaken. To address this problem, merchants
allowed buyers to take possession of goods in return for a promise of repayment
in the future. Despite the obvious risks involved, merchants were willing to
extend this favor as long as they could be convinced of the buyers “Integrity
and Ability for Payment.5,100 According to Defoe, this was the first
appearance of credit and it possessed all its mysterious qualities right from
the start. He writes:
CREDIT is a Consequence, not a Cause; the Effect of a Substance,
not a Substance; ’tis the Sun-shine,
not the Sun; the quickning SOMETHING,
Call it what
you will, that gives Life to Trade, gives Being to the
Branches, and Moisture to the Root; ’tis the Oil of the Wheel, the Marrow in the Bones, the Blood in the Veins, and the Spirits in the Heart of all the Negoce, Trade, Cash, and Commerce in the
World.101
Here he combined discourses of metaphysics, natural philosophy,
mechanics, and medicine, and even invited readers to provide their own
metaphors for this “quickning SOMETHING, Call it
what you will!' While this confusing mix of
metaphors highlighted the essential, but mysterious, role of credit in society,
he did not pretend to contribute towards a more precise definition.102
Defoes primary aim here was to establish that even though the phenomenon of
credit escapes human intelligibility, it was nevertheless absolutely essential
to modern society and should therefore be protected at all cost.
Having established that credit is capable of generating great
benefits to a modern commercial society, Defoe proceeded to investigate the conditions
under which credit thrives. The most essential feature required for credit to
flourish was “universal Probity.”103 For Defoe, credit grows
steadily as long as people commit themselves to “fair and upright Dealing,
punctual Compliance, honourable Performance of Contracts and Covenants.”104
All the ingenuity in the world cannot conjure up credit in the absence of such
probity, and all the money in the world will not raise credit in the absence of
honesty and punctuality. Moreover, where there is probity and justice, all
other barriers to establishing trust and credit are superseded. He exemplified
this by asking, “How do we Trade among the Turks, and Trust the Mahometans, one of whose Doctrines, in the Alchoran, is, not to keep Faith with Christians?”105 Defoe
answered that “They have obtain’d it by a just, punctual, and honourable
Practice in Trade, and you Credit them without
Scruple; nay, rather than a Christian.”106
In singling out probity as the universal and exclusive criterion for trust and
credit, Defoe reiterated the point that public credit was not tied to any
specific minister, but could be raised by any able and prudent person. After
all, he insisted, if an Englishman can trust a prudent Muslim, it should not be
that difficult for him to trust one of his own, so long as he exhibited proper
virtues and character. Hence, similar to Boyer, Defoe believed that if people
of honor, probity, and character were put in charge of the Treasury and
Exchequer, the precariousness of public opinion would be reduced and so would the
instability of credit. For Defoe, Godolphin provided an excellent example of
the kind of person it would take to stabilize public credit.
Defoe also commented on what he saw as an absurd Whig threat: that
the investing public would refuse to purchase government bonds because of
loyalty to the former ministry. To predict this outcome was, to Defoe, the same
as saying that “Nature will cease [and] Men of Money will abstain from being
Men loving to get Money.”107 Defoe shared this sentiment with
Clement, who argued that the investing public, regardless of political
conviction, would always purchase government bonds as long as they were backed
by good security and offered an adequate rate of return. For him, the
marketplace was largely impervious to political ideology.
It is possible to reconcile Defoes and Clements views that people
did not trade against their economic interests with the claim made by
sociologist Bruce Carruthers that both Whigs and Tories were observed trading
in ways that supported their respective party’s political agenda.108
Since each party s propaganda machinery encouraged investors to internalize a
certain set of ideas about the present political situation and particular
expectations about the future, the investors5 outlook and expectations
would be such that their individual economic interest would coincide with the
party's overarching aim. Successful propaganda for the Whigs, for example,
therefore meant that investors were convinced that it was in their financial
interest to sell bonds after the dismissal of Godolphin and thus further sink
public credit, while the opposite was the case for the Tories. As such, many
investors entered Exchange Alley to transact stocks and bonds primarily to augment
their own wealth, while inadvertently ending up contributing to the political
interest of the party they supported. This, of course, does not rule out that
there were some who intentionally compromised their economic interest to
promote political ends in the market for stocks and bonds.
Defoe tried hard to convince his audience that party strife or
religious disagreement would not keep investors from buying bonds issued by
the government, as long as Parliament secured its loans with a stable revenue
flow and prudence and probity informed the management of the public debt. What
did matter, however, was that it was clearly conveyed to the public that the
states fiscal administration was indeed managed properly. For this purpose, it
was important that the recording
of
the conditions of the public debt was accurate and transparent.109
As Simon Schaffer has shown, since Defoe believed that “Social life should be
reported the way nature was,,,he advocated marshalling modern empirical methods in the world of
finance so that it would appear intelligible and predictable to investors.110
If merchants and government officials kept meticulous accounts of their
finances and allowed them to be witnessed firsthand by the public, the
credibility and trustworthiness of credit instruments could increase and there
would be less room for public opinion and imagination to run amok. The focus on
firsthand observation as the key to the formation of sound opinion, articulated
by Locke and others, continued to constitute one of the cornerstones of credit.
The Tories thus tried to ground public opinion in the same principles as
private opinion. People should ignore secondhand accounts and propaganda, and
instead personally gather as much information as possible on which they would
base their own views. Only then would credit rest on a solid foundation.
Clearly, Harleys writers were trying to convince the public to dismiss the fact
that the government bonds were trading at a discount, attributing this to the
confused assessment of public opinion, rather than any underlying weakness in
the government or its ministers.
Defoes treatment of credit was far from universally admired. In
the Whig periodical The Medley, Arthur Maynwaring put forth a biting critique of Defoes ideas,
the vehemence of which may have been enhanced by Defoes recent betrayal of the
Whigs.111 Maynwaring ridiculed Defoes pronouncements that he would
clear up the conceptual issues surrounding credit and suggested that he instead
led his readers into a maze of obfuscations. He sardonically stated, “what a
Scholar he is, where he speaks of something that is neither Quantity or Quality y has no Whereness or,
Whenness, Scite or Habit. There’s Philosophy for you,
Sir.”112 He then provided a point-by-point satirical commentary on
Defoes essay, concluding that Defoe failed so miserably in his arguments that
he actually ended up undermining his support of Harley. Maynwaring criticized
Defoe’s exaggerated claim that all of the responsibility for public credit
rests exclusively on Parliament and the queen, thus removing all the blame from
the ministers themselves and making it largely irrelevant who served in this
capacity. This constituted, in Maynwarings mind, a
strikingly lukewarm endorsement of Harley.
A month later, Maynwaring continued his attack on the Tory claim
that credit depends on no particular person, using many of the same arguments
previously employed by Hoadly. The absurdity of this proposition had become
manifest during the autumn, he claimed, when the Exchequer Bills dropped below
par as an immediate consequence of the ministerial change. These securities had
previously been impeccably managed by people of solid reputation, but now that
these managers were removed, the resulting anxiety led the public to shift
their wealth elsewhere. Maynwaring concluded, “Interest being the most
impatient, as well as the most timorous thing in nature,,,uncertainty,
regardless of cause, will always make money change location.113
Maynwaring also addressed Clement’s critique of “imaginary value,” suggesting
that it was ridiculous to claim that something was worth less than its price.
He dismissed this notion as a complete misunderstanding of the very nature of
credit, which enables expectations and the imagination to generate values
greater than that which is immediately present.
Unfazed by Maynwarings criticism, Defoe continued to defend the
Tory position, now with even more elaborate imagery. In a series of articles in
the Review
during the autumn of 1710, Defoe famously revived the figure of Lady Credit,
which he had introduced a few years earlier.114 He described Lady
Credit as the younger sister of money, who has the capacity to take moneys
place in trade, as long as “her Sister constantly and punctually relieves her.”115
Using a set of gendered stereotypes, he portrayed Lady Credit as
temperamental, coy, fickle, over- emotional, prone to hysteria, but also
beautiful, charming, and capable of great wonders.
Part of Lady Credit’s volatility and irrationality stemmed from
her faulty empirical assessment of the world. Instead of observing and recording events and phenomena in a
rational manner, she filtered her impressions through her
imagination. As Pocock observes, “not only were the data on which opinion was
formed at least partly imaginary, but even those well founded in concrete
reality figured to the imagination …as features of a mobile . .. universe in
which every object was
potentially a source of either profits or loss, a subject of both hope and
fear.”116 Whether she would interpret something as a sign of hope or
a cause for fear was impossible to gauge for the outside world, leading to a
great deal of uncertainty and indeterminacy. It was thus impossible to predict
and control her mood swings. If she had once been badly treated by a suitor,
she would always take a long time to return. Or, as Defoe put it, recovering
lost credit “is almost as Difficult as to restore
Virginity, or to make a W____ re
an Honest Woman.”117 Not even kings
or Parliaments could force or bribe her to make an appearance. The
best way to ensure that she came around was to pretend that she was not wanted.
However, once she arrived she had to be constantly attended to with flattery
and praise.
Despite her tendency towards inconstancy and fickleness, when Lady
Credit flourished she was capable of bringing great fortunes, which she happily
spread throughout society.118 In an article published on August 8,1710,
the day of Godolphin s dismissal, Defoe recalled how Lady Credit had been
exuberantly happy during the last decade under the guidance of Godolphin. He
described how she “was always Smiling and Pleased, Gay and in Humour—Her walk
was daily between the Bank and the Exchequer, and between the Exchange and the
Treasury; she went always UnveiFd, dress’d like a Bride; innumerable were her
Attendants, and a general Joy shew’d itself upon the Faces of all People, when
they saw her.”119 But now, with the intensification of Whig-Tory
hostility, her temper had worsened and it was generally feared that she would
experience one of her dreaded epileptic seizures.120 Unfortunately,
her fate was far worse than just the falling sickness.
Here Defoe departed slightly from the established Tory position. Contrary
to Clement’s and Boyers, as well as his own efforts to remove the focus from
Godolphins personal role in the flourishing of public credit, he acknowledged
the Whig claim that public credit had benefited greatly from Godolphins
reputation and skill In the very next issue of the Review, Defoe explained how with
the dismissal of Godolphin, Lady Credit lost her “best Friend, that ever she
had in this Nation; a Friend that had restor’d her Languishing Condition many a
time, when she was at Deaths Door.,,121 Defoe further described how she “is deeply sensible of the Loss,
she is almost inconsolable for the Disaster, and how it will go with her.”122
Everywhere people mourned the impeding death of Lady Credit. In his imaginary
account, Defoe visited the Bank of England, Exchange Alley, and the Exchequer
and found the same desperately somber mood. The only people to express a
certain joy at the news of the Lady parting from her best friend were the
Tories, who had been responsible for engineering the ministerial shift. But
even they felt a mounting uneasiness about what they had done and started to
worry about the consequences of their actions. Defoe offered the Tories little
solace, telling them: “if she did die, they had Murther’d her.”123
Defoe added to the insult by claiming that the Tories had no one
in their camp who could save her. This statement took on an added significance
in light of the queens announcement on that very same day—August 10, 1710—that
Harley would become the new Chancellor of the Exchequer. Defoe’s lack of public
support of Harley is puzzling. If indeed Defoe was already on Harleys payroll,
it is surprising that Defoe was so critical of the Tory position and Harley
himself. In particular since Defoe wrote in a letter to Harley, “It is with a
Satisfaction …I can Not Express, That I See you Thus Establish’d Again •..
Providence Sir Seems to Cast me back Upon you (I write that with Joy).”124
It is conceivable that Harley wanted to keep his patronage of Defoe still
secret or perhaps Defoe did not want to appear unrealistically partisan and
thus jeopardize his reputation. Two weeks later, however, Defoe started to
sound more approving of recent changes. While he still paid tribute to
Godolphin—“I could be content to spend a whole Page in his Praise”一 his message and tone were now more supportive of Harley.125
Nevertheless, Defoes defense of Harley remained lukewarm throughout 1710.
This, however, would change the following year when Defoe became the most
vociferous champion of Harleys proposed financial panacea.
In
closing, public credit constituted one of the primary battle grounds between
Whigs and Tories. Yet, there were nevertheless a number of principles that both
sides shared. As Pocock points out, “An anatomy of the great debate as between
landed’ and ‘monied’ interest, conducted by the journalists and publicists of
Anne’s reign, reveals that there were no pure dogmas or simple antitheses, and
few assumptions that were not shared, and employed to differing purposes, by
the writers on either side.,,126 The landed elites were still anxious about the weakening of the
traditional political and moral order in which power and authority originated
from property in land. For them, organizing society around land ensured that
nature’s scarcity reigned in the potential excesses of commerce and finance and
that the moral virtues exhibited by the landed men increased the likelihood of
a stable polity. Yet, they increasingly acknowledged that trade and mobile
property had the capacity to contribute substantially and favorably to the
political and economic order, as well as provide a solid security for public
credit. In particular, after the failure of the land bank venture in 1695,
their notion of credit increasingly came to approximate that of the moneyed
interest. Both groupings agreed that public credit was based most fundamentally
on reputation for prudence and probity, solid revenue flows earmarked for the
service of loans, transparent reporting, and favorable expectations of the
future. While the Tory landed interest had earlier favored existing assets like
land and merchandise as securities backing financial assets, the Tories were
now more open to backing credit with expectations of future profits, even
though public opinion would then play a more prominent role. While the Tories
approached the Whig position on the issue of what kind of asset is most
appropriate as security, the Whigs would soon become increasingly uncomfortable
with public opinion. Both sides thus agreed that the influence of an unpredictable
public had turned public credit into a dangerous source of instability. The
fact that an amorphous and not-quite-real public opinion made credit into a
fickle, precarious, and, most importantly, uncontrollable force was perceived
as a major threat to the prosperity and security of England.
The
Evolution of Harley’s Panacea
While the debate about credit raged on, Harley struggled to ensure
that Hoadly, Maynwaring, and the rest of his detractors’ writings did not go
unanswered. He was able to keep credit afloat, if only through temporary
measures, by appealing to the Bank of England for short-term loans. Harley knew
that these loans served as mere palliatives and that he would soon have to
pursue more radical solutions. In October of 1710, he began exchanging ideas
with two members of the controversial Sword Blade Bank—John Blunt (d. 1733) and
Sir George Caswall (d. 1742)—about an ambitious scheme that would engraft the
entire unsecured national debt into the capital stock of a new joint-stock
trading company. The shares of this company would be exchanged for the outstanding
government bonds, on account of the prospective dividend and capital gains
generated by the company’s trade. Blunt argued in a letter to Harley that this
conversion would eliminate the burden of the national debt and, in so doing,
wipe off “entirely that unjust reproach which ill men so industriously spread
of the danger of the public funds and credit, but also must encourage all
persons to lend their money the more freely.”127 This was a
brilliantly clever proposal, according to Caswall, who wrote to Harley that it
would “promote the retrieving publick
credit and give great honour to those in the Administration who
shall appear zealous for its execution.”128 It was not the first
time that such a financial technique had been used. In 1697, the Bank of
England engrafted some £800,000 of depreciated short-term government bonds.
These bonds were incorporated into the capital stock of the Bank by offering
its holders stocks in the Bank in return. The Bank carried out another such
engraftment in 1709,when it expanded its capital
stock and exchanged shares for £1,775,028 of discounted Exchequer Bills.129
The Sword Blade Bank also engaged in a similar scheme in 1702, when it took in
£200,000 of discounted army debentures in exchange for shares in the company.130
With the help of Blunt and Caswall, Harley now had the basic outline
of what he hoped would become a swift and convenient solution to the nations
most pressing challenge. During the course of the autumn of 1710, he convinced
the queen of the necessity of restoring public credit and the importance of
relieving the unfunded portion of the debt. In November, during her first
address to the newly elected Tory-dominated Parliament, the queen highlighted
this problem and impelled the members to act quickly to find a feasible
solution.131 She proclaimed “that the Navy, and other offices, are
burdened with heavy debts, which so far affect the public service that I must
earnestly desire you to find some way to answer these demands and to prevent
the like for time to come.”132 Finding a solution to the ailing
public credit had now been elevated to the highest national priority. Harley
had to figure out where the new company would obtain the revenues that would
service the reconstruction of the unfunded debt. He still had some thinking
to do before he could announce his panacea.
After months of teetering on the brink of disaster, the ailing
trust and confidence in financial markets finally took a turn for the better in
December of 1710. Ironically, it was the announcement of Spain’s victory over
England at Brihuega that provided the long-sought medicament. This military
defeat calmed financial markets because it put an end, at least for the moment,
to the Whig strategy of “No Peace without Spain” and thus eliminated a serious
cause of friction between the directors of the Bank of England and Harley.
After the defeat, a more convivial relationship emerged, facilitating the
stabilization of the Exchequer Bills and the renewal of the Banks discounting
of foreign bills of exchange. A further sign of credits recovery came in
March of 1711, when a Bank-organized lottery loan was
oversubscribed on the first day. The lottery loan’s offer of a two and a half
percentage point higher interest rate than recently issued government bonds
was apparently enough to sway the public. The proceeds of £1.5 million were
used to alleviate the most pressing claims on the military departments,
ensuring that the armed forces were able to properly prepare for the summer
campaigns. Considering the desperate condition of public credit that had
prevailed just a couple of months earlier, the success of the lottery loan was
a significant display of vigor and perhaps a sign that public opinion had
shifted in Harleys favor.
Everyone was not convinced that the recovery of credit was real.
Defoe remained only cautiously optimistic and once again employed the allegory of Lady Credit to voice his
concerns. Writing in
the Review in
February of 1711,he describes how in a recent dream he came across “POOR CREDIT! sunk
and dejected, sighing and walking alone; I met her t other Day in the Fields, I
hardly knew her, she was so lean, so pale; look’d so sickly, so faint, and was
so meanly dress’d.”133 She had told him that she was contemplating
leaving England to go to France where she was hoping to encounter a more
conducive atmosphere. She was resentful of the treatment she had received in
England, in particular considering all the great gifts she had bestowed on this
nation and its people. She complained that “now my Face is Threatened to be
wash’d with a Spunge; for which of all my Bounties have I deserv’d these
Things?”134 What frightened her most was that financial property
rights may no longer be safe in England. Echoing Hoadly,s earlier argument, Defoe suggested that a default on the national
debt would constitute a massive violation of private property, which would
undoubtedly lead to a complete societal breakdown. Defoe tried as best as he
could to assure Lady Credit that the present Parliament, ministry, and queen
understood the situation well and that all forms of property would be secure as
long as the Pretender was not invited back to impose a rule of absolutist
tyranny.
The attempt to convince the public that a return of the Pretender
would put public credit at great risk soon became a bipartisan concern. Defoe
was joined by the leading Whig periodical, The
Spectator, in trying to ensure that a newly
elected Tory majority would not listen to the party’s Jacobite elements and
hatch a plan for the restoration of the Pretender to the throne. On March
3,1711, Joseph Addison (1672-1719) offered an account of a recent dream, in
which he had encountered Lady Credit at the Bank of England.135 She
was pictured as a abeautiful Virgin, seated on a Throne of Gold,”
with the halls around her “covered with such Acts of Parliament as had been
made for the Establishment of Publick Funds.”136 She frequently
looked at these acts to reassure herself that her health and safety were
protected. However, as soon as the news of even the least threatening event
reached her, she turned nervous and fidgety. Attributing a similar set of
gender stereotypes to Lady Credit as Defoe had done previously, Addison
described her as emotionally unstable and easily prone to hysteria. At a
moments notice, “she would fall away from the most florid Complexion, and the
most healthful State of Body, and wither into a Skeleton.”137
Addison recalled the dramatic event when the doors of the great hall flew open
and in walked a threatening group of ghosts, the most hideous and frightening
being the Pretender. To the great despair of Lady Credit, he had “a Sword in
his right Hand, which ... he often brandished at the Act of Settlement; and a
Citizen, who stood by me, whisper’d in my Ear, that he saw a Spunge in his left
Hand.”138 This ghostly display was too much for the Lady’s delicate
disposition, causing her to faint promptly.
Jonathan Swift, writing under Harleys patronage, dismissed any
concerns about a second Stuart Restoration and instead proclaimed that Lady
Credit was in remarkably good condition.139 While the market in
private stocks might be in a sickly state, he argued in The Examiner that public credit was
perfectly fine: “By the narrowness of their Thoughts, one would imagine they
conceiv’d the World to be no wider than Exchange Alley. ’Tis probable they may
have such a sickly Dame among them, and,tis
well if she has no worse Diseases, considering what Hands she passes through.
But the National Credit is of another Complexion; of sound Health, and an even Temper,
her life and Existence being a Quintessence drawn from the Vitals of the whole
King- dom.”140 Swift argued that the success of the lottery loan had
restored public confidence in credit and that even the most vociferous opponents
had started to change their opinion. He observed that “we find these Mony-Politicians, after all their Noise, to
be of the same Opinion, by the Court they paid Her, when she lately appear’d to
them in the form of a Lottery!ym
In addition to credits portrayal as a lady, opinion was ascribed a similar set of gendered traits. Sir Richard Steele (d. 1729),
Addisons
which is thus managed by the breath of Opinion, deluded by Errour,
fired by Self-Conceit, and given up to be trained in all the courses of Vanity,
‘till Scorn or Poverty come upon us.”147 This frank criticism of
England’s political authority quickly drew the attention of the guards, who
violently brought the man into custody. But, it was already too late. The
comments had already unleashed a powerful force that brought the Palace of Vanity to an apocalyptic end. As
numerous harpies, including Broken Credit,
Poverty, Infamy, and Shame, entered the building, Vanity and her entourage were
forced to flee. Once they disappeared from sight, the palace slowly descended
towards the ground and eventually made contact with earth. Steele was not sure
that everyone in the palace was aware of this return to basic grounded
principles, but he woke up from his dream before he could find out.
Steele depicted Popular Opinion as a dangerous and deceptive force that twisted the minds of the
multitude and facilitated the Tory ministry s bubbling and corruption of the
nation. He illustrated the dynamic of what happens when political propaganda
writers successfully infiltrate public opinion. Once the propaganda was
absorbed by public opinion, more and more people were swayed, even without
informing themselves about the underlying merits of the claims. As such, public
opinion became a force for delusion, irrational speculation, and corruption.
Referring to Harleys successful propaganda machinery, Steele claimed that
public opinion had of late been systematically manipulated to undermine reason
and honesty in politics, as well as to raise the credit of a fundamentally
corrupt ministry. Hence, while Hoadly had defended public opinion when it was
in favor of the Whigs, now that it had turned in favor of the Tories, Whig
supporters such as Addison and Steele harshly
criticized it. The only solution, in Steeles mind,was to silence the charismatic rhetoric of Popular Opinion and reintroduce the
quintessentially English virtue of honest Plain-dealing. This was the only way that the power of Popular Opinion, delusion of Errour, and the corruption in the Palace of Vanity could be banished.
Through
their allegorizations of Lady Credit and Popular Opinion’ Defoe, Addison, and Steele highlighted the imaginary and
insubstantial character of credit and opinion. They portrayed credit and
opinion as fictitious phenomena, but with real political and economic power.
Since credit, opinion, and fiction operated on the same epistemic plane somewhere
between reality and the imaginary, these writers found fictional portrayals of
social, political, and economic forces particularly useful in their attempts to
shape credit. It was not a coincidence that Defoe and Swift, two of the
period’s greatest fiction writers, were employed as propagandists to mold
public opinion.148
England’s governing elites recognized the importance of finding a
solution to the ongoing crisis of public credit. Some commentators blamed the
Godolphin ministry for having abused the nascent system of public credit, while
others claimed that it was Harleys inexperience and lack of reputation that had
caused the “Loss of the City.” Harleys supporters tried to defuse the intense
criticism from the Whigs by shifting the blame for the instability of public
credit to the inherent precariousness of public opinion. Lacking in reasoned
judgment and careful empiricism, public opinion was dangerously fickle and
mutable, posing a serious threat to the prosperity and safety of both the
state and the nation.149 Harleys advocates, however, argued that as
long as the fiscal apparatus was under the sound stewardship of virtuous,
prudent, and principled men, that bookkeeping was impeccable and transparent,
and financial securities were adequately backed, public opinion would
eventually form a positive judgment of credit and thus enable its many
benefits.
While the recently improved conditions of credit served as a sign
of the publics growing acceptance of Harley, the ever-present specter of the
Pretender led both Defoe and Addison to hoist a warning flag. To Harley, the
focus on the Pretender was a most welcome, or perhaps even scripted, distraction.
Since neither Defoes Review nor Addisons and Steeles Spectator focused on Harley as a burden on public credit, Harley had now
gained some valuable room to maneuver. This breathing room, combined with the
success of the lottery loan, suggested to Harley that the time was now ripe
for him to go public with his financial panacea. The formal announcement was
delayed, however, by an unfortunate incident in which Harley was stabbed by
Marquis de Guiscard, a French adventurer and spy. The wounds inflicted by the
assailants penknife would ordinarily not have been life-threatening, but
because Harleys underlying health was poor, he experienced some serious
complications. During his recovery, his supporters took advantage of the
favorable public sentiment and published a series of uncontested propaganda
pamphlets.150 Defoe, for example, provided his thus far strongest
endorsement of Harley in A Spectators Address
to the Whigs, on the Occasion of the Stabbing Mr. Harley (1711). He claimed that recent developments
had revealed clearly to all that Harley had not only saved the nation from the Whig Juntos mismanagement, but that he alone
had the capacity to mediate successfully between extremes in party politics and
church affairs. To Defoe, Harley also deserved praise for his vigorous
prosecution of the war against the Great
Enemy, as well as for how “His Management restores Credit, confirms past Funds, raises New, banishes the
Peoples Jealousies about the Spunge; raises Money in spight of Pretences of being Exhausted.”m Given
these accomplishments, only Jacobites, papists, and supporters of French
tyranny could oppose Harley. This propaganda campaign was extraordinarily successful,
paving the way for Harley to return to the political scene stronger than ever.
The timing was now perfect for his grand announcement. On May 2,he presented to the House of Commons his plan for the resolution of
the nation’s public credit crisis: the South Sea Company.
沒有留言:
張貼留言