2019年10月1日 星期二


CHAPTER FOUR
Swiss bankers are trained to believe that there is a higher goal than making profits. Their priority has been to retain "triple A" credit ratings, the badge of good banking.
rokkrt prkston, Financial Times, 1992

The three supporting arguments about debt rating are germane to the rating of corporations. What are the implications of investment judgment centralization in the corporate world? In what ways does the rating of corporate bonds demonstrate the subjectivity of the rating process and the dominance of instrumental knowledge? How significant is rating to the activities and organization of market institutions? What ideas are articulated in corporate rating, and how best should these be interpreted?
In pursuing these questions, the counterfactual method introduced in chapter 1 is used to contrast rationalist and constructivist accounts. In counterfactual analysis, the factor thought most likely to be causal in the phenomena under consideration is excluded from a second, alternative scenario. In these changed causal conditions, if a different result seems likely, it is probable that the correct causal element was identified in the initial analysis. In developing these scenarios, principles derived from the oppos­ing dimension of the mental framework of rating orthodoxy (table 5 in chapter 3) are deployed. So, if a synchronic-rationalist argument is developed as the primary analy­sis, diachronic-constructivist principles inform the second, counterfactual scenario.
The kind of bonds which I want to be connected with are those which can be recom­mended without a shadow of a doubt, and without the least subsequent anxiety, as to payment of interest, as it matures.1
1. J. P. A lorgan, quoted in Ron Chernovv, The House of Morgan: An American Banking Dynasty and the Rise of Modern Finance (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1991), 37.

Rating Corporations 73

The following analysis of investment in relation to corporate rating has three ele­ments: the relationship between rating levels and the typical cost of debt, the nature of the agencies' power, and the agencies' scrutiny of the automobile industry.
Rating and the Cost o f Debt
Ratings affect the cost of issuing debt. Other things being equal, shifts in prevailing interest rates determine the price that issuers must offer to attract funds into their market away from other investment opportunities, such as Treasury bonds, the stock market, and real estate. The particular characteristics of the debt instrument itself also influence its cost; for example, whether a bond is backed by a sinking fund, in which the issuing company sets aside revenue for debt repayment.2 However, apart from interest rates and these other issues, the primary factor that distinguishes between different bonds is the creditworthiness of the issuer.
The effect of rating can be understood by comparing the cost of rated and unrated debt, and the difference in yield spread in basis points between highly rated and lower-rated issues. One study indicated that getting a rating can create savings of $0.66 million on a $200 million bond issue, over a twenty-year term.3 Although there is little disagreement about this effect, there is controversy about the impact of subsequent downgrades on yield spreads. It is often unclear whether the market has already anticipated the rating agency's actions and discounted the issuers' cred­itworthiness by the time the agency makes an announcement.4 In any case, it is clear that rating has a major influence on the cost of capital to corporations that issue debt.
Rating Power in the Corporate World
The rating constraint and the relatively high interest rates banks charge on loans led to the re-emergence of a high-yield (or junk bond) market in the late 1970s. That market was based in part on the work of Michael Milken, formerly of the invest­ment firm Drexel Burnham Lambert. Milken's arguments about capital access and the credit rating system and his activities as the "junk bond king" during the "junk bond decade" (1977-87) remain the subject of considerable dispute.5
During his graduate education at the University of Pennsylvania's Wharton School in Philadelphia, Milken read W. Braddock Hickman's work on returns in the bond market.6 Hickman claimed that low-grade or junk bonds promised high
2.    Staff of the New York Institute of Finance, How the Bond Market Works, 1988, 175-76.
3.    Study by Stephen Dafoe, analyst, Canadian Bond Rating Service, Montreal, June 1992.
4.       Interview with Brian I. Neysmith, president, Canadian Bond Rating Service, Montreal, June 16,1992.
5.       See, e.g., Benjamin J. Stein, A License to Steal: The Untold Story of Michael Milken and the Conspiracy to Bilk the Nation (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1992).
6.       W. Braddock I Iickman, Corporate Bond Quality and Investor Experience (Princeton: Prince­ton University Press, 1958).

74 The New Masters, of Capital

yields when held in large numbers in a diversified portfolio by "large permanent investors." He suggested that these returns more than compensated for the addi­tional default risk of the lower-rated debt.7 A recent study, which incorporates data from the junk decade, has drawn the stronger conclusion that in the context of a well-diversified portfolio, the risk of lower-grade bonds was actually "no greater" than that of investment grade bonds.8
According to Bailey, Milken formed the view that ratings had, over time, "be­come moral absolutes" among investors.9The view that ratings are really judgments, as in the diachronic-constructivist account, had been firmly displaced by the ortho­dox notion, derived from the synchronic-rationalist account, that ratings are the result of rational professional processes. Following some of Hickman's conclusions, Milken observed that downgraded bonds "were held in more contempt by investors than they deserved to be." Like some of the investment trade journal writers of the time, Bailey claims Milken saw that the primary problem with the ratings process was that it was too much based on past performance. However, bonds were obliga­tions for future payment, and even an AAA rating was "no guarantee" against a sub­sequent default. According to Bailey, Milken frequently observed that of the twenty-three thousand U.S. companies with sales of more than $3 million, only 5 percent could secure investment grade ratings. The rest had to turn to bank or insur­ance company loans, with their higher interest rates, short-term maturities, and restrictive covenants, or to equity, which was yet more expensive and meant dilut­ing corporate control.10
Milken saw two major problems with the historical approach the agencies used. First, their focus was on assets and liabilities, or debt/equity ratio analysis, when in his view cash flow really determined a company's ability to service its debt, given that holdings of current debt were always refinanced. Second, he believed the agen­cies were not really interested in the "intangibles" of corporate performance he thought so important: management skill, strategic thinking, and innovation." This rationale underpinned Milken's promotion of junk bonds to clients. He endeavored to show there was more value in these bonds than the agencies, other investors, or even their issuers had believed.
7.     Ibid., 26.
8.       Marshall E. Blume and Donald B. Keim, "Risk and Return Characteristics of Lower-Grade Bonds, 1977-1987," in Edward I. Altman, ed., The High-Yield Debt Market: Investment Perfor­mance and Economic Impact (Homewood, 111.: Dow Jones-Irwin, 1990), 15.
9.       Fenton Bailey, The Junk Bond Revolution: Michael Milken, Wall Street and the Roaring Eight­ies (London: Fourth Estate, 1991), 25.
10.   Ibid., 25,26, 29.
11.     Jesse Kornbluth, Highly Confident: The Crime and Punishment of Michael Milken (New York: William Morrow, 1992), 41; also see Bailey, 1991, 29, and Robert Sobel, Dangerous Dreamers: The Financial Innovators from Charles Merrill to Michael Milken (New York: John Wiley, 1993), 70.

Rating Corporations 75
Milken's career as a bond underwriter and trader came to a close in late 1988, when he was charged and later convicted of a series of SEC disclosure violations, spending two years in a U.S. federal penitentiary.12
According to Toffler, Milken attempted to establish a new order in the financial industry. As Toffler saw it, the industry was "hidebound and protected" and a "major barrier to change." Only smokestack, blue-chip industrial "dinosaurs" could get long-term investment capital, because the two rating services "guarded the gates of capital."13 Toffler observed that conflict between those (like J. P. Morgan) who wanted to "restrict access to capital so that they themselves could control it," and those like Milken, who supposedly sought a "democratization of capital," has a long history in the United States and elsewhere.14 Whatever Milken's motivations, the result of the initiative of Milken and others, as Grant has noted, was that "marginal" borrowers "received the benefit of the doubt" in the 1980s.b This tendency threat­ened to foster an "emerging power structure" that would change the "game," as Grant put it.16 According to Bruck, "Milken had long professed contempt for the corporate establishment... whose investment grade bonds, as he loved to say, could move in only one direction—down."1'
The broader movement to change credit standards posed a challenge to estab­lished relationships on Wall Street and in corporate America. In ten years at Drexel, Milken had raised $93 billion, and the junk bond market had grown to $200 billion, serving more than one-thousand, five hundred companies.18
Milken was no revolutionary. He was a critic of prevailing assumptions about securities and their creditworthiness, applying his own understanding of the diachronic-constructivist principles elaborated in table 5. Although never spelled out in a systematic way, his analysis, following Hickman, was actually a social one. That is, he saw the judgmental and interpretive content in the agencies' rating processes.
During the 1980s, lobbying efforts to review high-yield financing were launched, organized by the Business Roundtable (representing the Fortune top 200 corpora­tions), the American Petroleum Institute, and others. Thirty-seven U.S. states sub­sequently passed restrictive legislation to control leveraged buyouts. Congressional testimony into junk financing suggested that Milken's indictment sealed the fate of
12.  Sobcl, 1993,215.
13.    Alvin Toffler, Powershift: Knowledge, Wealth, and Violence at the Edge oft he Twenty-First Cen­tury (New York: Bantam, 1990), 44^17. (Stephen Gill suggested the relevance ofToffler's work.)
14.  Ibid., 49-50.
15.    James Grant, Money of the Mind: Borrowing and Lending in America from the Civil War to Michael Milken (New York: Farrar Straus Giroux, 1992), 437.
16.   Ibid., 393, quoting a Business Week article, "Power of Wall Street," July 1986.
17.    Connie Bruck, The Predators' Ball: The Inside Story of Drexel Burn ham and the Rise of the Junk Bond Traders (New York: Penguin, 1989), 12.
18.    Glenn Yago, Junk Bonds: How High Yield Securities Restructured Corporate America (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), 25.

76 The New Masters, of Capital

Drexel's high-yield operations and the use of junk bonds to finance LBOs.'9 Wyss observed that the tax deductibility of interest paid on debt and the nondeductibil- ity of dividend payments (on equity) established an incentive structure that favored debt growth in corporate America. Milken's operation was built on these incentives and was evolving into a relationship finance system similar to what Zysman observed in Germany. This would be "inconceivable" in the United States, and "possibly ille­gal." Milken's indictment put a stop to this development. Wyss suggested that the "indictment said to the market, you cannot shift in this direction."20
The testimony of rating agency officials revealed their opposition to what they called the "extreme financial leverage" attributable to the junk bond financing of LBOs in the late 1980s.2' Bachmann emphasized probable constraints on innova­tion, as well as the tendency of managers to sell assets and skimp on strategic plan­ning under such heavy debt loads.22 Grant, a noted Wall Street newsletter publisher and writer, cast the net wider in his testimony. As he saw things, in the 1980s, "Every American with a mailbox was invited to borrow."23 He blamed this "explosion of the credit supply" on "the long-standing tendency toward the socialization of credit risk that had its roots in the reforms of the early 1930s." Milken had to be understood, Grant implied, in terms of a profligate US government whose net worth in 1988 was negative $2.5 trillion.24 As Wyss noted in response to questions, the government had subsidized junk-financed LBOs as well. First, it had allowed deductibility of inter­est payments.21 Second, it had required pension funds' equity assets (but not fixed- income or debt assets) to be marked down to current market value rather than nominal or book value.26
Milken applied heterodox principles to rating, based on an implicit diachronic- constructivist understanding of the rating agencies and their work in the 1970s and 1980s. The effect was to contribute to the disinter mediation of U.S. finance, a
19.     Testimony of David A. Wyss, senior vice president, DRI/McGraw I lill, "High Yield Debt Market/Junk Bonds," hearing before the Subcommittee on Telecommunications and Finance of the Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives, 101st Cong., 2nd sess., Mareh 8, 1990 (Washington, DC.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1990), 3-4.
20.   Ibid., 7, 8,3-4,42.
21.     Testimony of Mark Bachmann, senior vice president, Corporate Finance Department, Standard & Poor's Ratings Group, "High Yield Debt Market/Junk Bonds," hearing before the Subcommittee on Telecommunications and Finance of the Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives, 101st Cong., 2nd sess., Mareh 8, 1990 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Gov­ernment Printing Office, 1990), 12.
22.   Ibid., 13.
23.     Testimony of James Grant, Gram's Interest Rate Observer, "High Yield Debt Market/Junk Bonds," hearing before the Subcommittee on Telecommunications and Finance of the Committee on Energy and Commerce, House of Representatives, 101st Cong., 2nd sess., Mareh 8, 1990 (Washington, D.C.: US. Government Printing Office, 1990), 18.
24.   Ibid., 22.
25.   Wyss, Mareh 8, 1990, 34.
26.   Ibid., 46-47.

Rating Corporations 77

process that actually expanded the agencies' potential scope of operations. Ironically, if Milken's purpose was to break out of an orthodoxy, the longer-term implication of what he did was to hasten the centralization of finance around debt issuance, for a wider range of companies. Although an immediate problem for the agencies, this challenge had much the same effect as the Asian financial crisis: the rating system did not displace centralization but instead increased its reach.
In a counterfactual scenario, the absence of Milken's alternative intellectual road map about rating and its efficacy would have retarded efforts to build a junk bond market. Disintermediation would have advanced less rapidly because lower-grade companies would have had to finance their operations through bank loans. Rating agencies would be important for a smaller group of companies, the investment cen­tralization process would be less advanced, and the agencies would be less powerful than they otherwise became.
Rating and the Automobile Industry
Rating agencies can at times be understood to "directly intervene in the affairs of a corporation."27 A useful example of this power is the effect of rating downgrades on U.S. automakers, including General Motors (GM) and the Ford Motor Company. These cases do not support an argument that the ratings made were "wrong" or oth­erwise deficient. Instead, by showing the impact of the agencies through ratings, these cases support the claims about investment centralization identified as the first mid-range argument. As argued in the preceding chapters, power and politics are not synonymous with institutionalized politics but pervade social and economic life. In a diachronic-constructivist view of the agencies, ratings are an exercise of power prior to considering the consequences of specific ratings.
At the end of 1991, GM announced a "disastrous $4.5 billion loss" on opera­tions.28 Subsequently, the corporation declared that it would close twenty-one plants and cut seventy-four thousand jobs.29 According to Cox, this action "was intended, by appearing as a token of the corporation's intention to increase competitiveness, to deter a downgrading of its bond rating which would have increased the corpora­tion's cost of borrowing."30 The perceived threat of a downgrade was reinforced by the Wail Street Journal, which noted that the potential rating reduction had "hung heavily" over Robert C. Stempel, GM's chairman, and had "pushed" him to speed restructuring plans.31

27.     Beth Mintz and Michael Schwartz, "Sources of Intercorporate Unity," in Schwartz, ed., The Structure of Power in America: The Corporate Elite as a Ruling Class (New York: Holmes & Meier, 1987), 30.
28.    Kathleen Kerwin, James B. Treece, and Zachary Schiller, "GM Is Meaner, But Hardly Leaner," Business Week, October 19, 1992, 30.
29.   Joseph B. White and Bradley A. Stertz, "GM's Debt is Downgraded by Moody's," Wall Street Journal, January 8, 1992, A2.
30.     Robert W. Cox, "Global Restructuring: Making Sense of the Changing International Polit­ical Economy," in Richard Stubbs and Geoffrey R.D. Underhill, eds., Political Economy and the Changing Global Order (Toronto: McClelland & Stewart, 1994), 48.

78 The New Masters, of Capital

However, Stempel's strategy did not work. The corporation was downgraded by Moody's in January 1992, and by Standard & Poor's in Mareh of that year.32 In explaining their action, Moody's officials said the automaker's restructuring plans were unlikely to solve its competitive problems.33
Pressure on GM from the agencies did not end with these downgradings. According to Judith H. Dobrzynski of Business Week, "The prospect of sinking credit ratings that would deny it access to equity and commercial paper, eventually prompted independent directors" to pressure GM's "old guard," as personified by Chairman Stempel, to quit in late October 1992.34 Subsequently, the agencies issued further warnings of downgrades, including the possibility that GM's debt might be relegated to junk bond status.35 The agencies subsequently acknowledged improve­ment in GM's operating performance. But what seems to have led the agencies to further downgrades in late November 1992 and February 1993 were unfunded pen­sion and medical benefit liabilities. These liabilities threatened to seriously compro­mise GM's balance sheet.36 As S&P observed,
Servicing its massive benefits obligations will be a substantial drain on the company's financial resources—and a significant competitive disadvantage—for the foreseeable future.... GM's unfunded pension liability increased to $14.0 billion at year-end 1992, from $8.4 billion one year earlier. . . . The company has reported a retiree medical lia­bility of $24 billion. . . . Adjusting for these liabilities effectively eliminates GM's con­solidated net worth.3'
Fearing this sort of judgment, which hampered General Motors Acceptance Cor­poration (GM's finance company subsidiary) by raising the cost of commercial paper sales, GM was forced to raise bank loans instead of selling bonds.

31.   White and Stertz, 1992.
32.   Joseph B. White, "General Motors Debt Ratings Are Cut by S&P," Watt Street Journal, Mareh 16, 1992, A2.
33.   White and Stertz, 1992.
34.     Judith H. Dobrzynski, "A GM Postmortem: Lessons for Corporate America," Business Week, November 9, 1992, 87; Kathleen Kerwin, James B. Treece and Zachary Schiller, "Crisis at GM: Turmoil at theTop Reflects the Depth of it Troubles," Business Week, November 9, 1992, 84.
35.    Joseph B. White, "S&P Issues New Warning on GM Stock," Wall Street Journal, Novem­ber 12," 1992, A3.
36.     Ibib., Joseph B. White and NealTemplin, "GM to Disclose More Details on Pension Gap," Wall Street Journal, November 16,1992, A3; Joseph B. White, "GM's Ratings on Debt, Paper Cut by Moody's," Wall Street Journal, November 25, 1992, A3; Kathleen Kerwin, "GM Isn't Running on Fumes—Yet," Business Week, November 30, 1992, 35-36; and Joseph B. White, "GM Ratings Are Downgraded by S&P, But Stock Jumps on Car Sales Data," Wall Street Journal, February 4, 1993, A4. Pension deficits became a systemic issue ten years later: Alexander Jolliffe and Tony las- sell, "Deficits on Pension Funds May Hit Credit Ratings," Financial Times, August 7,2002, 2; Sil­via Ascarelli, "Pension Deficits Threaten Ratings of Twelve Companies," Wall Street Journal Europe, February 10, 2003, Ml.
37.    Standard & Poor's, "General Motors Corp. and Related Entities," Standard & Poor's Cred­it week, February 22, 1993, 44, 46.

Rating Corporations 79

The agency "completed | the largest bank credit package ever," with the attendant extra burden of intermediation.38 GM also sought funds by issuing relatively high-cost equity capital in response to reduced credit ratings on its debt financing.39
Counterfactually, if wc exclude the 1992 and 1993 downgrades, it is unlikely, given the relative cost of bank versus debt finance and the dilution of governance inherent in further issuance of equities, that GM would have sought these alterna­tive forms of financing willingly. The probability is that in the absence of the down­grades GM would have continued to issue debt securities.
The power rating agencies exercise—reflecting investment centralization—was more recently experienced by Ford. Long considered the best managed of the Big Three automobile manufacturers, Ford had embarked on an ambitious strategy in the late 1990s to reinvent the corporation as a consumer company. In the words of its former chief executive officer, Jacques Nasser, Ford "happens to provide automotive products and services."40 Nasser planned to use the Internet to transform how the company did business by cutting out dealers, thereby reducing the cost of selling cars. Unfortunately for Nasser, those plans began to come unstuck after 1999, with the dot-com bust and the onset of recession in the United States in 2000. Ford's usual rate of return on total capital of about 10 percent slipped to 9 percent in 1999, and then to 6 percent in 2000.41 Prior to the September 11, 2001 terrorist attacks, Ford sales had slumped 12.7 percent during July. The market itself slipped 5 percent.42
It was a bad year for the Big Three in 2001. Recession made consumers hungry for deals in the summer and fall, including zero percent financing of new cars and trucks, especially after the terrorist attacks. Each deal of this sort cost around $3,000 per vehicle to the automakers.43 This financing expanded sales and overall sales numbers were not much lower than in 2000, a boom year.44 According to S&P, "Sales for full-year 2001 will likely total in the range of 16.2 million to 16.4 million units, making this year the third-best sales year ever. (The best year was 2000, with 17.3 million units; 1999 was the second-best, with 16.9 million units)."47 The problem was, sales also grew at Honda, Toyota, and premium European brands, even though

38.    "GM Secures $20.6 Billion in Credit Eines with Banks," Wall Street Journal, May 20, 1993, A3.
39.  Kerwin, November 30, 1992; White, November 12, 1992.
40.   James Flannigan, "Basics, Not Free Loans, Will Help Auto Firms," Los Angeles Times, November 4, 2001, pt. 3, p. 1.
41.  Ibid.
42.    Keith Bradsher, "Ford Weighs Plans to Cut White-Collar Work Force," New York Times, August 17, 2001, sec. C, 1.
43.    Terril Yue Jones, "S&P Drops Boom on Ford, GM," Los Angeles Times, October 16, 2001, pt. 3, p. 1.
44.    Standard & Poor's, "Big 3 Automakers' Credit Quality Deteriorates," October 16, 2001, available at www.standardandpoors.com, accessed February 5, 2001.
45.  Ibid.

80 The New Masters, of Capital

these companies did not offer free financing. Even though the Big Three sold a lot of cars in the last quarter of 2001, little profit was actually made on these vehicles. Tastes were changing, and the imports were tough competition. Foreign makers were producing better SUVs (sport utility vehicles) than the U.S. makers, who had introduced the concept and made most of their profit on these vehicles in the 1990s.
In addition to the market problems that afflicted all the Big Three, Ford had spe­cific problems of its own. Ford incurred liabilities of around S3 billion to replace thirteen million Firestone tires it blamed for accidents on its SUVs and light trucks.46 The company faces a series of lawsuits related to these accidents. An S&P analyst observed that the Firestone affair "at least has been a major distraction and affected productivity and quality. . . ."4/ These quality problems have been signifi­cant. An auto dealer observed that "Ford went from the penthouse to the outhouse on quality," as CEO Nasser pushed component manufacturers to produce at lower price points.48

S&P and Moody's began to suggest that a crisis was developing at Ford in the spring of 2001. S&P had put a "negative outlook" on Ford in February. According to Scott Sprinzen, S&P's automotive industry managing director, the agency had been "warning actively" that Ford's rating "could possibly be lowered within a few quarters."49 On May 22, Moody's changed the outlook for Ford from stable to neg­ative, anticipating possible future downgrades.10 Ford responded toward the end of the summer with the announcement of five thousand white-collar layoffs, mainly in the Detroit area, at a cost of $700 million. Ongoing savings were projected at $300 million annually in salaries and other costs.1' According to Bradsher, S&P was not impressed and said Ford's "efforts to reduce costs have been inadequate."
Immediately, S&P put Ford (and General Motors) on credit watch, with a view to possible downgrade. According to fait, S&P's move reflected "growing misgiv­ings" about profit prospects.52 Ford stock sank 8 percent (and GM's lost 5 percent) in reaction.13 Moody's began to review Ford "for possible downgrade."54 Bonds of

46.    Jack Sirard, Jack Sirard Column, The Sacramento Bee, August 21, 2001, 8, Lexis-Nexis, accessed February 5, 2002.
47.    Terril Yue Jones, "S&P Drops Boom on Ford, GM," Los Angeles Times, October 16, 2001, Part 3,1.
48.    James Flannigan, "Basics, Not Free Loans, Will Help Auto Firms," Los Angeles Times, November 4, 2001, part 3,1.
49.    Keith Bradsher, "Ford Weighs Plans to Cut White-Collar Work Force," The New York Times, August 17, 2001, CI.
50.   www.moodys.com, accessed February 5, 2002.
51.    Keith Bradsher, "Ford to Curtail Auto Production and Cut 5,000 Jobs," The New York Times, August 18, 2001, Al.
52.    Nikki Tait, "Ford Cuts 5,000 Jobs in North America; Automobiles Fierce Competition Forces Carmaker into Restructuring," Financial Times, August 18, 2001, 15.
53.   Ibid.
54.    List of rating actions for Ford Motor Company at www.moodys.com, accessed February 5,2002.

Rating Corporations 81

both companies traded "lower in the secondary market since the agencies' state­ments." 55   As often occurs in these situations, the markets anticipated the likely future downgrades following these announcements, considering it, in the words of Morley, a "fait accompli."56
S&P acted on October 15 by downgrading outstanding long-term debt from A to BBB+, while Moody's downgraded from A2 to A3 on October 18.57 S&P was more bearish than Moody's, signaling that a future rating downgrade, if any, might push the credit into the noninvestment grade or junk bond area. S&P noted, how­ever, that a "further rating change within the next few years was unlikely. Present ratings reflect the expectation that financial performance could be relatively weak for a sustained period.The severity of the S&P move was unexpected and led to a 10 basis point increase in Ford's bond spread.59
How did Ford react to the downgrade? Like GM, Ford said in one breath that it was unfortunate and not necessary and, in the next, that "plans" were being devel­oped to take action.60 A few days after the rating announcements, Ford said the cor­poration planned to go into the capital market to sell $3 billion in bonds in a market that, since the downgrades of a few days earlier, had widened by between 15 and 20 basis points.61 Subsequently, Ford changed this plan and decided to sell $7.5 billion worth of securities, just after announcing a $692 million third-quarter loss.62 According to Wiggins of the Financial Times, the "positive ruling" by Moody's on Ford Credit, the Ford consumer credit company, encouraged Ford to increase the size of the deal. Moody's, noted Wiggins, saw Ford Credit as a better risk than the automaker itself.63
Although it might seem that Ford was not affected by the ratings actions in 2001, the opposite was actually the case. Ford lost access to the short-term market because its rating fell below the crucial A1 /PI benchmark, required by most money market funds. Ford then had the problem of how to finance its existing short-term borrowings, pushing it into the long-term debt market”64

55.     Rebecca Bream, "Ford and GM Ratings in Focus," Financial Times, August 21, 2001, p. 27.
56.     Kevin Morley, co-head of investment grade researeh at Credit Suisse First Boston, quoted in Jenny Wiggins, "Further Rating Fall for Ford Expected," Financial Times, August 24, 2001, p. 25.
57.     As detailed in the respective web sites.
58.     Standard & Poor's, "Ford Motor Company," www.standardandpoors.com, accessed Febru­ary 5, 2002.
59.     Rebecca Bream, "Motor Vehicle Spreads Widen," Financial Times, October 16, 2001, 37.
60.     On GM, see Nikki Tait, "S&P Lowers Debt Ratings on GM and Ford," Financial 'Times, October 16,2001,32; on Ford, see Jamie Butters, "Ford, GM Get Lowered Credit Ratings," Detroit Free Press, October 15, 2001, 7, Lexis-Nexis, accessed February 5, 2002.
61.     Rebecca Bream and Jenny Wiggins, "Ford Plans $3 Billion Bond Issue," Financial Times, October 19,2001,35.
62.     Reuters, "Automaker Plans to Sell $7.5 Billion in Bonds," New York Times, October 20, 2001, sec. C, 4.
63.     Jenny Wiggins, "Ford Doubles Its Bond Issue Size to $7.5 bn," Financial Times, October 20, 2001,18.

82 The New Masters, of Capital

The worsening credit conditions for big issuers like Ford shrank the proportion of short-term assets in money market funds from 36.7 percent in early 2001 to 34.5 percent, as of Octo­ber 2001.65
Nasser, Ford's CEO, Internet visionary, and cost-cutter, was removed from his position at the head of the company on October 30, 2001. Chairman William Clay Ford Jr., who took over Nasser's CEO duties, said Ford would return to its "core business" of building cars and trucks.66 The financing program continued, espe­cially in the asset-backed market, where Ford sold $5 billion worth of securities in January/'7 Soon after, on January 11, Ford announced its Ford Revitalization Plan. The plan included new products, plant capacity reduction, asset sales, reduced div­idends, and about thirty-five thousand job losses for salaried and hourly workers. These actions were projected to improve results by $7 billion annually and by as much as %9 billion by the mid-2000s.68
The plan was "not well received" by the agencies. Fitch downgraded, and both Moody's and S&P announced their ratings might be downgraded, too.69 S&P affirmed its BBB4-, but it changed the outlook for Ford to negative from stable. On January 16, Moody's downgraded Ford from A3 to Baal. In addition to the automaker, this time Moody's also downgraded Ford Credit and Hertz, Ford's rental car subsidiary. The bad news at Ford continued into 2002 and 2003, despite the turn­around efforts.70
Ford's experience with bond rating reflected a more assertive rating industry, underpinned by the growth of capital market financing and its corollary, the central­ization of investment judgment. At first glance, the rationalist view of rating appears most viable in this case. Counterfactually, had rating agencies not closed off Ford's access to the short-term money market in 2001, the policy and personnel shifts at the company in early 2002 may have been delayed. However, the rationalist account does not capture the whole picture. In addition to the closing off of market access, Moody's and S&P's rating actions, warnings, and commentary gave the markets a developing view of Ford.

64.   Lex Column, "Corporate Bonds," Financial Times, October 25, 2001, 24.
65.    Jenny Wiggins, "Funding Dries Up for Commercial Short-Term Paper," Financial Times, October 30,2001,32.
66.   Ford quoted in Flannigan, November 4, 2001.
67.     Adam Tempkin, "Plain Vanilla Tastes Good: Ford's $5 billion ABS Deal Sets the Pace in a Strong Market," Investment Dealers Digest, January 7, 2002, Lexis-Nexis, accessed February 5, 2002.
68.    PR Newswire, "Ford Motor Company Announces Revitalization Plan," January 11, 2002, Lexis-Nexis, accessed February 5, 2002.
69.    The Associated Press State and Local Wire, "Ford Credit Rating Lowered by One Com­pany, on Notice from Two Others," Lexis-Nexis, accessed February 5, 2002.
70.     Norihiko Shirouzu, "Ford's Turnaround Stalls on Downgrade," IVall Street Journal Europe, October 17, 2002, Al; "Junkyard Blues; Ford Motor Company; Fresh Talk That Ford Might Go Bust," Economist, Mareh 15, 2003, 77.

Rating Corporations 83

This view or inter subjective understanding helped to define the context in which the market audience interpreted Ford's operations. Moody's and S&P's actions fell short of being a crisis of fact, but they managed to create an atmosphere of crisis at Ford, this crisis being a social fact. Ford's experi­ence with the agencies can, therefore, in part be understood in constructivist terms.
Rating agencies reproduce an instrumental form of knowledge through their work. This knowledge form reduces the scope for social conflict over ideas to those that fit within narrow purposive assumptions. How knowledge definition occurs is a vital political battle, which takes place before issuers can even begin to debate appropri­ate policy choices and strategies for internal change.
The rise of a ratings "advisory" industry is evidence that instrumental knowl­edge dominates within the rating agencies. Traditionally, investment banks advised their clients on how to present themselves to raters. With the rise of the high-yield market, greater interest on the part of global issuers in selling bonds in the Yankee market, more innovative financing by U.S. and foreign municipalities, and the expansion of domestic bond markets, former rating officials started to establish busi­nesses to take advantage of their knowledge of the rating process. On the whole, these are small enterprises with, at most, a handful of staff. Two of the most prominent are Cantwell & Company in the New York metropolitan area and Evei ling Advisory Services in Frankfurt, Germany.71 Cantwell publishes an annual survey of attitudes to credit rating.
The advisory services are useful in a context in which rating agencies may meet with a rich multinational on a Tuesday and a mid-size tool-and-die maker the fol­lowing day. Often former raters themselves, the advisers are more likely to under­stand the culture of the rating agencies than investment bankers, immersed as they are in a different environment. The existence of these services underlies the percep­tion that presentation is key to better ratings, judgment is a fundamental part of the rating business, knowledge can be organized in different ways, and the rating process requires knowledge to be presented in ways that meet raters' expectations. More substantially, the existence of advisory firms highlights the increasing pervasiveness of a culture of monitoring.
For rating advisory firms, the cause of their existence is the role of perception and intersubjective understanding in the rating process. If, in an alternative scenario, we remove perception and intersubjectivity, the need for issuers to focus on presen­tation is eliminated (along with these firms).

71. Cantwell's web address is www.askcantwell.com. Ever ling Advisory Services can be found at www.everling.de.

84 The New Masters, of Capital

Confirming the initial causal claim about these firms supports the diachronic-constructivist views of knowledge (the right side of table 5) in the mental framework of rating orthodoxy. These heterodox claims focus on the social dynamics of knowledge, as opposed to the idea that knowl­edge is objective and cross-cultural.
How does the agencies' rating of corporate debt securities promote instrumen­tal knowledge? The agencies make it appear their decisions are the product of a sci­entific process impartial toward all involved parties. As was noted in chapter 2, rating agencies acknowledge in their publications that ratings reflect both qualitative and quantitative information and analysis; the final product is therefore inherently sub­jective. However, the agencies do not make an issue of this subjectivity in their press releases. By not making it clear that their decisions are judgments, they foster the popular myth that rating actions reflect simply the facts revealed by economic and financial analysis. Consequently, they make it seem that any clear-thinking person, possessed of the right sort of knowledge, would come to the same view.
Issuers are also involved in this process. They are not above using rating agencies to justify rapid changes in corporate structure, which may have dire consequences for employees.72 This process of "referring back to the agencies" reinforces the notion that their judgments are somehow different and that they have the secret to the "right" way of thinking. Ratings emerge as a valid framework for thinking about corporate decision-making.
The instrumental form of knowledge is at the center of rating analysis, and its logic helps reinforce the synchronic organization of capitalist enterprises. This syn­chronic organization influences everyday life, shaping the experience of work and the expectations of employers and of government. It is as if there is a tension in cap­italism, between private property on the one hand and growth on the other. The rat­ing process normalizes capitalism by regulating it, just as computers do the engines of modern cars. In normalization, the historically diachronic character of capital­ism—its boom and bust, its inherent tendency to hubris followed by crisis—is demonized in an effort to regularize or tame it.'3 The rating experiences of the major telecommunications corporations during 2000 and 2001 demonstrate this tension.

72.     An example of this tendency to use the rating agencies to justify or explain change were pub­lic comments the Chrysler Corporation made in connection with Standard & Poor's 1993 upgrade. The upgrade, to the bottom rungs of investment grade, was an "endorsement" of Chrysler's "strategic direction" and an "acknowledgement of Chrysler's ongoing efforts to improve its cost structure, increase liquidity and reduce leverage"; see "Chrysler Sheds Junk Status at Second Credit Rating Firm," Toronto Star, October 5, 1993, D16.
73.     On these themes, see Joseph A. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York: Harper Torchbooks, 1976 [1942]); also see, among other entries, Alexander Ebner, "Schum­peter, Joseph Alois (1883-1950)," in R.J. Barry Jones, ed., Routledge Encyclopedia of International Political Economy (New York: Routledge, 2001), 1368-73.

Rating Corporations 85

Rating and Telecommunications

The 1990s were one of the most prosperous periods in recent history—at least for citizens of the rich countries—even though the decade began with a recession. The United States, Britain, and to a lesser extent Europe, enjoyed relatively high growth and a return to the optimism of the mid-1980s and, before that, of the mid-1950s to mid-1960s. Only Japan failed to return to the growth path. Before the Asian finan­cial crisis of 1997-98, there was much talk about Asian "tigers." The notion of "emerging markets" replaced that of "developing countries," for states like Taiwan, Malaysia, Thailand, and Korea.
The computer made enormous inroads into commerce and education in the 1980s. But the commercialization of the Internet in the mid-1990s brought a huge growth in expectations about the role computers would have in the lives of Western consumers. No longer would the computer be a glorified typewriter. It was net­worked and could talk to other computers. It is hard to exaggerate the enthusiasm that supported the digital revolution, especially in the rich countries, where cheap labor was not a competitive advantage.
Before the Internet revolution, telecommunications companies outside the United States were fairly staid institutions with conservative business strategies. Typically, they had the advantage of a government-protected monopoly and could pick and choose how and when to invest in new technology, at a rate that kept their finances in excellent condition. Once deregulation and liberalization of these mar­kets began in the late 1980s, all of this changed. Competition replaced the old regime of comfortable monopolies, jobs for life, and a three-month wait for a phone line. Suddenly, with the Internet revolution and the explosion of cellular phone use, tech­nology investment looked like a good way to beat the competition. But technology, especially new technology, is expensive, and the investments the phone companies contemplated in the late 1990s were huge.
Moody's estimated the total cost of introducing third-generation cellular phones, which deliver Internet-like services to customers, at around $270 billion. About half of this figure would pay for the technology, and the rest would go for the govern­ment licenses/4The subsequent cost of failure was high, too. S&Ps downgrading of France Telecom in July 2002 was estimated to add €110 million to the firm's exist­ing €3.85 billion interest bill for 2002, and €230 million in 2003.75
The ratings story starts with Deutsche Telekom's (DT) giant bond issue of June 2000. What was important about DT's $8-15 billion offering is that it was made with a guarantee: the coupon or interest rate paid would rise by 50 basis points (0.5 per­cent) if Deutsche Telekom's rating fell below single A into the BBB territory.

74.    Aline Van Duyn, "DT to Offer Protection for Downgrading," Financial Times, June 16, 2000, page 36.
75.    Vincent Collen and Jamal Henni, "Relating May Cost France Telecom €2bn," Financial Times, July 3, 2002, 21.

86 The New Masters, of Capital

Many fund managers avoid that rating as a matter of policy and, in some localities, as a matter of law. Things became bleaker for DT when Moody's downgraded to Baa3— the lowest investment grade.76 DT was following a trend Vodafone started during the $5 billion financing of its takeover of Mannesmann in early 2000. As Van Duyn explains, mergers or big technology investments can be interpreted as pitting the interests of shareholders and bondholders against each other. The benefits to share­holders from beating the competition—growth and increasing profits—are cap­tured (at least in part) by stock price. But bondholders can only ever hope to get back their principal plus the agreed interest payments. Even if a company hits the prover­bial growth jackpot, the debtholders share in none of it." Their only risk is "down­side,"—that the creditworthiness of the issuer will deteriorate—risking default and the loss of their investment.
Pressure from the rating agencies became evident in August 2000, when British Telecom (BT), DT, and the other major telecom players were put under review by both Moody's and S&P.78 Fears of a BBB rating delayed BT's $10 billion bond issue/' Moody's downgraded BT, an AAA company until early 1997, from Aal to A2 (but not as low as BBB) on September 6, 2000. This was good news in the sense that a high BBB would have cost BT at least 50 basis points. On $10 billion, 50 basis points equals $50 million a year—a considerable sum for any institution.80 Because the bond markets were so nervous about these issues, the telecom companies began to push their investment bankers to come up with bank loans instead.81 Subse­quently, Moody's did downgrade BT again, on May 10, 2001, to Baal. Mareoni, the telecom equipment manufacturer, had a worse time as the telecom companies held back on other expenditures. Its rating collapsed from investment grade down to B2 junk, in four downgrading events between August 8, 2001 and January 18, 2002.
In 2000 and 2001, the relative newness of the corporate bond market might have contributed to the anxiety in Europe about telecom debt. Moreover, speculative bond issues were new and the volume of debt unprecedented. Before 1990, corporate bond issues were rare. Those that did occur were typically undertaken by conservative companies in a conservative atmosphere.

76.     Stephanie Kirchgaessner and Aline van Duyn, "Moody's Deals Debt Blow to Deutsche Telekom," Financial Times, January 11-12, 2003, 15; Bertrand Benoit, "Investors Unswayed by DT Downgrade," Financial Times, January 14, 2003, 26.
77.    Aline Van Duyn, "Survey—International Mergers and Acquisitions," Financial Times, June 30,2000,9.
78.    Rebecca Bream, "Telecoms Get a Wake-up Call from Worried Bond Markets," Financial 'Times, August 22,2000, 1.
79.     Chris Ayres, "Delay for BT Bond over Credit Worries," Times (London), August 23, 2000. Also see Aline Van Duyn and Rebecca Bream, "Credit Rating Agencies Show Their Teeth," Finan­cial Times, February 27, 2001, 34.
80.    "Rising Debt, Sliding Credibility," Economic Times of India, Lexis-Nexis, accessed Febru­ary 3, 2002.
81.    Charles Pretzlik and Aline Van Duyn, "Indebted Telecoms Face Tough Times Finding New Lenders," Financial Times, October 6, 2000, 28.

Rating Corporations 87

The telecom issues of 2000—2001 really mark the beginnings of creditworthiness disaggregation in Europe, thus creating the basis for further work for the rating agencies. In America, the disaggregation had gone much further. According to Merrill Lynch, telecommunications bonds com­prised a full 18.6 percent of the U.S. high-yield bond market in the year to Septem­ber 30, 2000, ahead of the next-largest industry, cable TV at 8.63 percent.82
A contradiction is evident here. On one side is a fundamentally diachronic cap­italism of dramatically increased competition, technical innovation, and colossal investment of resources. On the other is the instrumental knowledge arising from the synchronic rationalist approach, which above all defends property rights. This contradiction has been noticed by market participants. Beyond obvious comparisons with the Milken era, Ravi Suria, formerly of the investment bank Lehman Broth­ers, suggested that telecom investment can best be compared to other big infrastruc­ture programs in modern history: electricity generation, railroads, highways, airports, ports. These investments were typically undertaken in a closely regulated environment or where monopolies ensured ready guaranteed income (as in the case of the railroads).83
Trying to finance such activities in conditions of globalization, with monitoring institutions like rating agencies—whose way of thinking is grounded in an entirely different logic, indeed a different form of knowledge—signals a profound shift. The hegemony of a social interest linked to growth and expansion gives way to an inter­est more narrowly concerned with the reproduction and safeguarding of its wealth.
The claim here is that the rating agencies produce knowledge actually at odds with the real life of modern capitalism. That world is one of change, typified by growth and decay. The form of knowledge at the heart of rating belongs, in a sense, to a Utopia of static social relations. Counter factually, if we were to remove syn- chronic-rationalist knowledge from rating determinations, actual rating decisions might take into account the circumstances Suria described, and the outcomes would be different. But if the risks of growth are not socialized away from investors, other mechanisms might be sought out by investors to compensate for the lack of instru­mental knowledge in the rating process. This counterfactual scenario supports the synchronic-rationalist account of knowledge. It suggests that before the advent of rating agencies, investors were, as the agencies like to suggest, poorly served.

Governance

The end of the postwar boom and the dynamic of mass production and consump­tion have corroded the economic and political hegemony of OECD institutions in sale difficulties),

82.    Gretchen Morgenson, "Bond Believers See Prelude to a Fall," New York Timea, November 19, 2000, sec. 3, p. 1.
83.  Ibid.

88 The New Masters, of Capital

the postwar era. Once-masterful institutions within civil society, such as commer­cial banks, have had their capacity for exercising authority substantially reduced by the way financial resources have been routed to borrowers. These transforma­tions have made the global economy a "risk culture."84 In this era, "The concept of risk becomes fundamental to the way both lay actors and technical specialists organize the social world."85 Risk monitoring becomes a central activity of elite reflection. More resources are devoted to "risk profiling—analyzing what, in the current state of knowledge and in current conditions, is the distribution of risks in given milieux of action."86 Among the types of risk evaluated are market risk (price fluctuations), liquidity risk (asset operational risk (such as fraud, computer error), exchange rate risk, and event risk (especially takeover threats and opportunities).87
In reacting to risk, the rating agencies foster models of corporate organization that challenge established governance structures. The global oligopoly, Moody's and S&P, advocates the capital market-centered system of control, corresponding to Zvsman's model.88 Their approach emphasizes the voting mechanism or "approval rating" available in liquid markets. When those with a financial stake in a corpora­tion do the " 'Wall Street walk': sell . . . wise bosses get the message."89 As Wood­ward noted of the bond market and the Clinton White House, rating provides a "barometer" with which corporate performance is checked regularly.90 This form of governance is different from the German and Japanese systems, where trusted inter­mediaries—banks—traditionally have undertaken the monitoring. Rating agencies constitute a new clearinghouse in which an "approval rating" is constructed and articulated to market agents.
Key ideas of this view of corporate governance can be gleaned from rating pub­lications. S&P includes a series of "organizational considerations" in its corporate criteria.91 The criteria emphasize that priority should be placed on the "finance func­tion" and that concentration in ownership potentially compromises management.

84.     Giddens, 1991,3; also see Ulrich Beck, Risk Society: Towards a New Modernity, trans. Mark Ritter (Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage, 1992); John Adams, Risk (London: University College Lon­don Press, 1995); and Stephen Gill, "The Global Panopticon? The Neoliberal State, Economic Life, and Democratic Surveillance" Alternatives 20, no. 1 (Jan-Mar 1995): 1-49, 28-29.
85.   Giddens, 1991,3.
86.   Ibid., 114, 119.
87.     See John Plender, "Through a Market, Darkly: Is the Fear That Derivatives Are a Multi- Billion Accident Waiting to Happen Justified?" Financial Times, May 27, 1994, 17, as cited in Gill, 1995, 28-29.
88.    John Zysman, Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Indus­trial Change, (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1983) 18.
89.   "Watching the Boss: A Survey of Corporate Governance," Economist, January 29, 1994, 4.
90.    Bob Woodward, The Agenda: Inside the Clinton White House (New York: Simon and Schus­ter, 1994), 224.
91.    Standard & Poor's, S&P's Corporate Finance Criteria (New York: Standard & Poor's, 1992), 19.

Rating Corporations 89

The agency also emphasizes the transition from "entrepreneurial or family-bound" to "professional and organizational" corporate control, although it does not define the latter.92 S&P's "organizational considerations" correspond to the neoliberal emphasis on "contestability," whereby control is contingent on performance as judged by owners, rather than other nonmaximizing criteria.93
Rating Japanese Banks
Japanese banks are no strangers to the rating agencies. The efforts of Moody's and Standard & Poor's to foster change in the Japanese financial industry go back a decade. Their activities parallel those of the U.S. government. U.S. agitation over Japanese regulation and market practices were evident in the yen-dollar negotiations of the mid-1980s and, more recently, during former Treasury Secretary Paul O'Neill's January 2002 visit to Tokyo, for discussions about the Japanese economic malaise.94 As Zysman has observed, the postwar role of banks in Japan was quite dif­ferent from the American model. Banks in Japan have traditionally been much more leveraged than Western institutions, because they support the industrial companies with which they are affiliated. Banks usually have much of their capital in corporate stock and, until recently, did not list this stock at current market value (or mark to market) on their books. Moreover, a history of cooperation between strong and weak banks prevented weaker institutions from going out of business. Subsequent changes in the regulatory system and the collapse of asset prices pose considerable challenges to this pattern.
It is a mistake to imagine that in Japan the rating agencies are able to exercise great power. Despite the poor record of Japanese finance in the past decade, Japan remains a rich country, with great resources and a strong desire to avoid change that gener­ates stark winners and losers. Current bank ratings reflect this approach by antici­pating some sort of government intervention to prop up ailing institutions. That occurred in early 1999, when the Japanese government infused 10 trillion yen into the banking system.95
From the beginning of the late-1990s banking crisis, the rating agencies were pushing Japanese banks to change how they did business. A series of downgrades began in 1997, prior to the failure ofYamaichi Securities in November—the biggest corporate collapse since World War II.96

92.     Ibid., 19.
93.     "Watching the Boss," January 29, 1994, 5.
94.     Tony Barrett, "U.S. Takes Hard Line on Japan's Bank Crisis," Sunday Business, January 27, 2002, 16.
95.     Standard & Poor's, "Japan Credit Trends 2002: The Downside Deepens," available at www.standardandpoors.com, accessed February 9, 2002, 6.
96.     Moody's began a review of Japanese banks in February of that year; see Gwen Robinson, "Moody's Reviews Japan Credit Banks," Financial Times, February 19, 1997, 33; on Yamaichi Securities, see "Bailout Pressure Rises in Japan," Boston Globe, November 26, 1997, C6.

90 The New Masters, of Capital

These events spurred Japanese banks to use financial innovation rather than balance-sheet improvement to get themselves out of trouble. In one case, S&P refused to rate a deal, leading to poor investor response and abandonment of the project. '' A Japanese regulatory agency found that banks had miscalculated their bad loans by about 10 percent in 1998.98
Many aspects of this story only get worse after the government bailout in early 1999. On Mareh 14, 2001, the banking sector lost 5 percent of its stock market value after Fitch announced it was reviewing nineteen Japanese banks for downgrade. Banks were still heavily exposed to the stock market at 150 percent of capital, com­pared to 10-20 perccnt in Western banks.99 Fitch observed in the fall of 2001 that bad loan statistics "grossly underestimate" the real level of nonperforming assets. Fitch suggested two things seem to constrain the banks from changing their busi­ness practices. One is a reluctance to get ahead of government and public sentiment toward restructuring and redundancy. The second is the "main bank" system, in which corporations buy bank equity in exchange for better credit terms, reciprocal equity purchases, and promises of support from the bank in bad times."10
As the fragility of the Japanese system became more apparent, even change seemed dangerous. Moody's signaled in January 2002 that an end to deposit insur­ance in April 2002 might be destabilizing, given the system's "grossly inadequate financial shape." Moody's pushed for a sharing of the burdens of adjustment.101 With the impending changes, forty-six credit unions collapsed in 2001, plus Ishikawa Bank, a larger regional lender.102 Moody's said subsequently it was losing confidence in the ability of the "Japanese system" to deal with the crisis.103 S&P fol­lowed Moody's announcements with further downgrades of its own.104 In a report on these actions, S&P made it clear that only government intervention could sup­port the existing level of ratings. The agency expected this intervention to continue after deposit protection ended, via the government's crisis management account.101

97.   "Japan Banks Resist Disclosure," Asset Soles Report International, Mareh 23, 1998, 1.
98.    Naoko Nakamae, "Japan's Banks Understated Risk)' Loans, Audit Shows," Financial Times, December 28, 1998,4.
99.   Doug Cameron and Emiko Terazono, "Japan Banks Face Possible Downgrade," Financial Times, Mareh 15, 2001, 34.
100. Fitch Inc., "Running Out of Borrowed Times," Banker; October 1, 2001, n.p., accessed via Lexis-Nexis January 20, 2002.
101. "Moody's Revises Major Japan Banks' Outlook to Negative," Jiji Press Ticker Service, Jan­uary 21, 2002, n.p., accessed via Lexis-Nexis Mareh 10, 2002.
102.  Ken Belson, "Jitters in Japan for Savers and Banks," New York Times, January 23, 2002, sec. W, 1.
103.  "Moody's Cuts Japan Banks' Ratings Outlook," Star (Malaysia), January 25, 2002, n.p., accessed via Lexis-Nexis.
104. "S&P Cuts Ratings on 7 Major Japan Banks, Affirms 4," Jiji Ticker Service, February 5, 2002, n.p., accessed via Lexis-Nexis.
105.  Standard & Poor's, "Ratings on Seven Major Japanese Banks Lowered, Four Affirmed," available at www.standardandpoors.com, accessed February 9, 2002.

Rating Corporations 91

In a wide-ranging report on credit conditions in Japan, S&P cautioned that things would get much worse before they got better and commented on the awareness among Japanese officials and market actors that meaningful credit risk was increas­ingly a fact of life. The report suggested a basic mismatch between assets and returns, and that Japanese banks have been "battling the incessant emergence of new bad loans since the collapse of the bubble economy in 1991 .",()6 Elsewhere, S&P observed that simply giving more money to the banks does not solve their problems. Banks had to "reform their lending practices, strengthen their corporate governance and improve their profitability.1"07 Moody's made further downgrades in July 2002.108 The case of Japanese banks is interesting because it is an example of confronta­tion between the rating agencies and historically entrenched norms and practices. Unfortunately, the problems have not been resolved even after a decade or more of problems. From a counterfactual perspective, if the agencies had not been willing to confront these historically derived norms in the Japanese banking industry, the Japanese government might have been less willing to socialize risk and (partly or temporarily) stabilize the system. This alternative scenario suggests that syn- chronic-rationalist considerations drove these rating actions but that politics had a role, too, in getting government to take responsibility. The diachronic-constructivist view of rating and how it works therefore contributes an important element to understanding the Japanese case.


In this chapter the three mid-range arguments were applied to the rating of corpo­rations. The emphasis of the section on investment was that rating makes a consid­erable difference to the cost of financing. The centralization of investment judgments was demonstrated by the struggle over junk bond financing and the LBO movement. The cases of General Motors and Ford also show the disciplinary effect of these processes in both more narrow rationalist terms and in a wider constructed sense.
In the section on knowledge, it was argued that rating advisory services are evi­dence that the rating process is judgment-filled. The agencies contribute to the con­struction of a synchronic, instrumental form of knowledge, by at all times seeking to appear as if their judgments, like those of auditors, are scientific and impartial.

106. Standard & Poor's, "Japan Credit Trends 2002: The Downside Deepens," available at www.standardandpoors.com, accessed February 9, 2002, 6.
107.        "S&P Cuts Ratings," February 5, 2002, n.p.
108. Bayan Rahman, "Moody's Downgrades Japanese Banks," Financial Times, July 3, 2002, 30. In September 2003, the Japanese government-backed bank recovery agency determined that many banks were overvaluing the collateral of borrowers, suggesting that many institutions could be underprovisioning for their bad loans (David Pilling, "Some Japanese Banks Found To Be Over­valuing Borrowers' Collateral," Financial Times, September 30, 2003, 14).

102 The New Masters of Capita I

There is a tension between the impulse to normalize capitalism around synchronic expert knowledge and the reality that major social investment in infrastructure, like telecommunications, has traditionally taken place in a broader diachronic context.
In the final section, on governance, it was shown that the agencies are key insti­tutions in which responses to risk are developed. The crisis-prone Japanese banks provide an example of how the agencies apply specific views of corporate gover­nance. Next, we examine how the agencies rate municipal governments.


CHAPTER THREE

Mr. Untermyer: You and Mr. Baker control the anthracite coalroad situation, do you not, together?
Mr. Morgan: No; we do not.
Mr. Untermyer: Do you not?
Mr. Morgan: I do not think we do. At least, if we do, I do not know it.
Mr. Untermyer: Your power in any direction is entirely unconscious to you, is it not?
Mr. Morgan: It is sir, if that is the case.
Pujo congressional hearings, 1912
Investment judgments, as we have seen, are increasingly centralized in rating agencies, rating knowledge is a social phenomenon becoming increas­ingly instrumental, and governance is assuming new forms more conducive to pri­vate interests and increasingly less subject to democratic intervention. In the following analysis of unconscious power, the conceptual and, in some cases, empirical basis of the mid-range arguments about rating and investment, knowl­edge, and governance are developed. From these arguments and the conceptual exploration undertaken here, a mapping of the norms that underpin rating work can be derived. This "map," or mental framework of rating orthodox}', sets out the assumptions implicit in rating agency judgments, offering an organized under­standing of rating norms and practices. Along with assumptions that comprise the dominant mental framework, the map also sets out opposites of these orthodox principles, to make the orthodoxy approximate contestable claims rather than fixed characteristics. The mental framework of rating orthodoxy is subsequently used in the empirical explorations of chapters 4-6, which consider corporate, municipal, and global rating.

Unconscious Power 51

All models of how to think about the world are vulnerable to the criticism that they are arbitrary.1 The focus on investment, knowledge, and governance reflects a view that these things matter in the conditions of early twenty-first century capital­ism, when considering the role and implications of rating agencies' judgments.


Investment is changing in form, and this transformation increases the potential power and influence of rating agencies. In chapter 1, it was argued that the central­ization of investment judgment is a key development underpinning rating power and authority. The basis of this centralization is considered here in three parts. One is the growth of disintermediation. Another concerns the forms of investment bond rating encourages. But before these points can be made, foundational arguments about the significance of bond rating should be examined, along with criticisms of these views and the case for a political-economy understanding of the agencies and what they do.
The views about rating that circulate in financial markets can be gleaned from many different sources, such as newspapers, other media, and surveys of market par­ticipants.2 Bond traders and pension fund managers have seemingly contradictory views of rating agencies. They are at times critical of the agencies' work. As Scott suggests regarding the public roles played by the powerful and the powerless, sepa­rate from a positive public discourse about the dominant is typically a "hidden tran­script," a critique of power existing as a sort of back-chat, spoken out of sight of the dominant.3 Back-chat only becomes public, suggests Scott, in times of crisis or unusual stress. But back-chat is just that. Financial market actors take the rating agencies seriously. Market participants usually treat the rating agencies and their views as matters of considerable interest. What the raters think is important to peo­ple in the capital markets, because people in the markets believe that the rating agen­cies know what they are talking about.
In addition to respect for the agencies' reputation, there is also an awareness of the markets' influence on the agencies.4 As Gary Jenkins, head of credit researeh at Barelays Capital, London, observed, "Love them or loathe them, if they did not
1.       The ontology used here is based on work by Cox; see his "Social Forces, States, and World Orders: Beyond International Relations Theory," in Robert W. Cox with Timothy J. Sinclair, Approaches lo World Order (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), 85-123.
2.       For example, the surveys undertaken bv Cantwell and Company since 1997 (interview with Joseph E. Cantwell, New York City, Mareh 2000); also see www.askcantwell.com.
3.       James Scott, Domination and the Arts of Resistance: Hidden Transcripts (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1990), xii.
4.       A recent confirmation of the growing importance of ratings can be found in the Japan Cen­ter for International Finance's 2001 survey on attitudes to bond rating, "Characteristics and Appraisal of Major Rating Companies (2001 ed.), 1; see www.jcif.or.jp/e_index.htm.

52 The New Masters, of Capital

exist, we would have to invent them."'' F.ven if a trader or a bond issuer does not respect a particular judgment, they might anticipate the effect of the agencies' judg­ment on others and may act on that expectation, rather than on their own views of the actual quality of the judgment. The intersubjective process described here is sometimes termed "Keynes' beauty contest," after J. M. Keynes' discussion of the similarities between financial market behavior and the tabloid newspaper beauty contests of the 1930s. In these competitions, the objective was not to guess who was the most attractive young woman but to approximate who was generally thought to he the prettiest by all competition entrants. On professional investment, Keynes argued, "We have reached the third degree where we devote our intelligences to anticipating what average opinion expects the average opinion to be."6
Rating agency outputs comprise an important part of capital market infrastruc­ture. They are key benchmarks in the cognitive life of these markets—features of the marketplace—which form the basis for subsequent decision-making by partici­pants. In this sense, rating agencies are important not so much for any particular rat­ing they produce but for the fact that they are a part of the internal organization of the market. So, we find traders referring to a company as an "AA company," or to some other rating category, as if this were a fact, an agreed and uncontroversial way of describing and distinguishing companies, municipalities, or countries.7
The rationalist way to think about what rating agencies do is to see them as serv­ing a function in the economic system. In this view, rating agencies solve the prob­lems that develop in markets when banks no longer sit at the center of the borrowing process.8 Rating agencies serve as "reputational intermediaries," like accountants, analysts, and lawyers, who are "essential to the functioning of the system" and mon­itor managers through a "constant flow of short-term snapshots."''
Another way to think about the agencies' function is to suggest they establish psy­chological "rules of thumb" that make market decisions less costly for participants.10
5.       Jenkins quoted in Charles Batchelor, "Companies and Regulators Go on Offensive in the Global Ratings Game," Financial Times, July 5, 2003, 3.
6.       John Maynard Keynes, The General Theory of Employment Interest and Money (London: Macmillan, 1936), 156.
7.       In a 1992 interview, President Leo O'Neill of Standard & Poor's explained how bond traders would, on the one hand, dispute particular ratings with S&P and, on the other, refer to companies unproblematicallv as AA, A, and so on. Ratings were the common sense of the markets.
8.       See, e.g., Richard S. Wilson, Corporate Senior Securities: Analysis and Evaluation of Bonds, Convertibles, and Preferreds (Chicago: Probus, 1987), 321-59; also see L. Macdonald Wakeman, "The Real Function of Bond Rating Agencies," in Joel M. Stern and Donald H. Chew, Jr., eds., The Revolution in Corporate Finance, 3rd ed. (Oxford: Blackwell, 1997), 25-28.
9.       Peter Gourevitch, "Collective Action Problems in Monitoring Managers: The Enron Case as a Systemic Problem," Economic Sociology- European Electronic Newsletter 3, no. 3 (June 2002); 1,11, available at www.siswo.uva.nl/ES, accessed June 12, 2002.
10. Jeffrey Heisler, "Recent Researeh in Behavioral Finance," Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments 3, no. 5 (December 1994): 78; also see Jens Beckert, "What Is Sociological about Economic Sociology? Uncertainty and the Embeddedness of Economic Action," Theory and Soci­ety 25 (1996): 803-40.

Unconscious Power 53

A functionalist historical analogy can be drawn with the law merchant, who dis­pensed commercial law in medieval times. The role of the law merchant developed as a means of enforcing contracts through judgments on trade disputes and record­keeping of these actions made available for scrutiny by those engaging in intra-Euro- pean trade. This mechanism backed up the reputation of traders when their names were not well known to potential new trade partners in geographically distant places, enabling, for example, a Burgundian trader in ribbons to sell to a Catalan haberdasher. Rating agencies share the information-provision and disciplinary characteristics of the law merchant. They, too, can be interpreted as part of a sys­tem that keeps an eye on who is violating the prevailing norms of financial and com­mercial practice.1'
Serving a "function" does not mean the institutions are free of criticism. Kerwer has suggested that the enforcement function evident in the work of rating agencies complements prevailing "standards"—or expertise-based voluntary rules—about creditworthiness. But this only works when the standard-enforcer is also account­able, he points out. Because rating agencies are not themselves seriously regulated, an "accountability gap" exists in rating.12 Kerwer concludes that there are insuffi­cient incentives to maintain the agencies' functional focus.
The rating agencies have a strong interest in developing and preserving their emi­nence as sources of judgment. This interest gives the agencies incentives to be as helpful as possible to investors. Paradoxically, they also have an interest in avoiding full disclosure of their information sources and ways of forming judgments. The agencies seem intent on preserving a sense of mystery surrounding the rating process in general—and any rating in particular—so as to reinforce their role in the capital markets.
Purely functional explanations for the existence of rating agencies are potentially deceptive. Attempts to verify (or refute) the idea that rating agencies must exist because they serve a purpose have proven inconclusive. Rating agencies have to be considered important actors because people view them as important and act on the basis of that understanding—even if it proves impossible for analysts to actually iso­late the specific benefits the agencies generate for these market actors.
Investors often mimic other investors, "ignoring substantive private informa­tion."13 People may collectively view rating agencies as important, irrespective of
11.     Paul R. Milgrom, Douglas C. North, and Barry R. Weingast, "The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs," Economics and Politics 2, no. 1 (Mareh 1990): 1-23; also see A. Claire Cutler, "Locating 'Authority' in the Global Political Economy," International Studies Quarterly 43, no. 1 (1998): 59-81, and Private Power and Global Authority: Transnational Merchant Law in the Global Political Economy (Cam­bridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2003).
12.    Dieter Kerwer, "Rating Agencies: Setting a Standard for Global Financial Markets," Eco­nomic Sociology—European Electronic Newsletter 3, no. 3 (June 2002): 5.
13.    David S. Scharfstein and Jeremy C. Stein, "I Ierd Behavior and Investment," American Eco­nomic Review 80, no. 3 (June 1990): 465.
54 The New Masters o f Capita!
what "function" the agencies are thought to serve. Markets and debt issuers there­fore have strong incentives to act as // participants in the markets take the rating agencies seriously. In other words, the significance of rating is not to be estimated like a mountain or national population, as a "brute" fact that is true (or not) irre­spective of shared beliefs about its existence, nor do the "subjective" facts of indi­vidual perception determine the meaning of rating.14
What is central to the status and consequentially of rating agencies is what peo­ple believe about them and act on collectively, even if those beliefs are demonstratably false. Indeed, the beliefs may be quite strange to the observer, but if people use them as a guide to action (or inaction) they are significant. Dismissing such collec­tive beliefs, as structural Marxists once did, as "false consciousness" misses the fact that actors must take account of social facts in considering their own action. Reflec­tion about the nature and direction of social facts is characteristic of financial mar­kets on a day-to-day basis. In investment, rating agencies are important most immediately because there is a collective belief that says the agencies are important and that people act on. Whether rating agencies actually add new information to the process does not negate their significance, understood in these terms.

Disintermediation

Changes in the financial markets have made people think the agencies are increas­ingly important. What banks do has undergone transformation under pressure from financial globalization.'1 A pattern of disenibeddcd investment has increasingly emerged, at least for "large and respectable borrowers."16
What is disintermediation? Bank loans have traditionally been the dominant means through which funds were borrowed and lent. Banks acted as financial inter­mediaries in that they brought together suppliers and users of funds. They borrowed money, in the form of deposits, and lent money at their own risk to borrowers. Those who deposited money in banks and those who borrowed from them did not estab­lish a contractual relationship with each other but with the bank.1'
14.     John Gerard Ruggie, Constructing the World Polity: Essays on International Institutionaliza­tion (New York: Routledge, 1998), 12-13; Ruggie draws on John Searle, The Construction of Social Reality (New York: Free Press, 1995). See also Peter L. Berger and Thomas Luckmann, The Social Construction of Reality: A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge (New York: Anchor, 1966).
15.     See Franklin R. Edwards and Frederic S. Mishkin, "The Decline of Traditional Banking: Implications for Financial Stability and Regulatory Policy," Federal Reserve Bank of New York Eco­nomic Policy Review 1, no. 2 (July 1995): 27-45.
16.    Daniel Verdier, Moving Money: Banking and Finance in the Industrialized World (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003), 17.
17.     On the concept of disintermediation, see Graham Bannock and William Manser, The Pen­guin International Dictionary oj Finance, 4th ed. (London: Penguin, 2003), 86; Timothy J. Sinclair, "Disintermediation," in R. J. Barry Jones, ed., Routledge Encyclopedia of International Political Economy (New York: Routledge, 2001), 355-56.

Unconscious Power 55

Figure 3. Trends in financial assets of institutional investors
US$ Bill 40,000
35,000
30,000
25,000
15,000
5,000
0
Source: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Financial Market Trends, No. 80, September 2001, p. 52.
Disintermediation has occurred on both sides of the balance sheet. Depositors are finding more attractive things to do with their money, just as borrowers have increasingly sought investment funds from sources other than banks. Mutual funds, which sweep depositors' money directly into financial markets, now contain $2 tril­lion in assets—not much less than the $2.7 trillion held in U.S. bank deposits.18 In 1994, 28 percent of American households owned a mutual fund, up from 6 percent in 1980. However, the proportion of household assets held in bank deposits fell from 1980 to 1990, from 46 to 38 percent.
The shift on the borrowing side is just as marked. In 1970, commercial lending by banks made up 65 percent of the borrowing needs of corporate America. By 1992, the banks' share had fallen to 36 percent, with the balance made up of various secu­rities.1'' Globally, bank lending decreased from 37 percent of total capital movements in the 1977-81 period to 14 percent in 1982-86. Portfolio investment, as opposed to direct forms of investment in plant and machinery, grew from 36 percent in 1972-76, to 65 percent of total investment in 1982-86. Most of this was funded through securities offerings.20
3 Loans H Shares PI Honds I | Others
ff, n, n
Fn ff n rf
~T
1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
18.  "Recalled to Life: A Survey of International Banking," Economist, April 30, 1994, 11.
19.  Ibid.
20.     These figures are taken from the International Monetary Fund, Balance of Payments Year­book (Washington: International Monetary Fund, various years), as cited in Randall D. Germain, "From Money to Finance: The International Organization of Credit," paper presented to the 1992 annual meeting of the Canadian Political Science Association, Prince Edward Island, Canada, June 1992,14.

56 The New Masters, of Capital

Emerging markets were traditionally dominated by bank-intermediated finan­cial systems.2' But a surge in domestic corporate bond issuance has taken place, especially in Asia and Latin America since 1997. As the Mareh 2003 Global Finan­cial Stability Report noted, "Domestic corporate bond issuance rose from 5 per­cent of total corporate domestic and international funding in 1997-99 to 31 percent in 2000-01."22 Domestic bank lending fell from 52 percent of corporate finance in 1997-99, to 40 percent in 2000-01. The authors of the report concluded that the trend to disintermediation is continuing.23 In developing countries, the effi­ciency of capital market financing is strongly promoted by World Bank and IMF officials.24
While the tendency in financial markets is toward disintermediation, the speed of this process varies widely throughout the world.2' Because of the shift from bank loans, stimulated in part by the advent of the Euro, the value of French corporate bonds grew from €2.5 billion in 1993 to €64 billion at the end of 2002.26 In some places, despite the continued reliance on bank loans, "the trend is toward a disinter- mediated, liquid, securitized structure."2' Even in Germany, the center of bank lending traditionalism, change is taking place.
In the 1990s, German banks tried to avoid the negative implications of global dis­intermediation for their market share by buying investment banks in London, through which they could participate in securities underwriting and trading. Ger­man companies are finding traditional bank lending inside Germany more expen­sive as local state-backed banks have had access to cheap capital "dramatically curtailed," making German credit more expensive.28 In this liberalized financial market, German companies have to seek capital market funding (or go without).
21.    International Monetary Fund, Global Financial Stability Report: Market Developments and Issues, Mareh 2003 (Washington, DC.: IMF, 2003), 75.
22.   Ibid.
23.   Ibid., 75, 11.
24.     On the World Bank's encouragement of capital market growth in emerging markets, see Clemente del Valle, "Government and Private Bond Markets: 'The Virtuous Circle,' " paper pre­sented to the 4th OECD/World Bank Bond Market Workshop on Developing Corporate Bond Markets, Washington, D.C., Mareh 7, 2002; for the IMF, see Gercl Hausler, "The Globalization of Finance," Finance & Development 39, no. 1 (Mareh 2002), available at www.imf.org, accessed April 28,2003.
25.     E.g., see Reinhard H. Schmidt, Andreas Hackethal, and Mareel Tyrell, "Disintermediation and the Role of Banks in Europe: An International Comparison," Working Paper no. 10, January 1998, J. W. Goethe University, Frankfurt, Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaften.
26.    Kevin J. Delaney, "France Inc. Is Fuming at Top Rating Agencies," Wall Street Journal Europe, November 20, 2002, Ml.
27.    International Monetary Fund, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues (Washington, DC.: IMF, 1992), 2-3.
28.    James Sproule, "What's Putting the Crunch on Germany?" Wall Street Journal Europe, Sep­tember 1, 2003, A7.

Unconscious Power 57

With the trend to disintermediation, "the largest banks have shifted into other lines of business."2'' Banks are not withering away, but they are increasingly engaged in other financial services.™ Banks remain banks in name, but the actual activities that define a bank are changing.31 Today, bank lending is a small feature of the work of diversified financial services companies.32 Thousands of banks that once made lending decisions on wholesale credit are now better described as financial market participants rather than market authorities. As the Economist suggested, "Banks have become increasingly market-based."33 Banks "bundle assets (loans) into securities and trade them; increasingly, they earn income from fees as well as from interest."
Investment Forms
What is the significance of this new way of borrowing and lending capital depicted in figure 4? It produces norms and practices that tend to encourage a specific invest­ment structure, at the same time raising the profile of the agencies and making them a focus of controversy.34 Variation across nations has historically characterized investment forms. Zysman identifies three major sets of postwar financial arrange­ments." The first of these, what he calls the capital market form, is typified by com­petitive price allocation, arm's length relations between government and industry, company-led market strategies, and the absence of conscious development policy. The second form, credit-based with government-administered prices, is designed to facilitate government intervention and state-led industrial adjustment. The last sys­tem Zysman identifies is a variant on the credit-based system, in which financial institutions use market power to influence industrial investment decisions by corpo­rations. Zysman sees the United States as the best example of the first system, Japan and France as exemplifying the second, and Germany as an expression of the third.
29.     Charles Gaa, Robert Ogrodnick, Peter Thurlow, and Stephen A. Lumpkin, "Future Prospects for National Financial Markets and Trading Centres," Financial Market Trends no. 78 (Mareh 2001): 37-72, 52.
30.     Biagio Bossone, "Do Banks Have a Future? A Study on Banking and Finance as We Move into the Third Millennium," Journal of Banking and Finance 25 (2001): 2239-76, 2260.
31.     Banks increasingly seek to earn income from fees for services and the development of new analytical products rather than traditional lending activity. Rebecca Bream, "Banks at Forefront of Rise in Credit Products," Financial Times, December 29, 2000, 21.
32.     "Crisis? What Crisis?" in "Capitalism and Its Troubles: A Survey of Internat ional Finance," Economist, May 18, 2002, 6.
33.     "The Trouble with Banks," in "A Cruel Sea of Capital: A Survey of Global Finance," Econ­omist, May 3, 2003, 12-14.
34.     Timothy J. Sinclair, "Synchronic Global Governance and the International Political Econ­omy of the Commonplace," in Martin Hewson and Timothy J. Sinclair, eds., Approaches to Global Governance Theory (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1999); and Delaney, November 20, 2002.
35.     John Zysman, Governments, Markets, and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Indus­trial Change (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983), 18, 94.

58 The New Masters, of Capital

Figure 4. Financing methods: Intermediation and disintermediation
Source: Modified from Arie L. Melnik and Steven E. Plaut, "High-Yield Debt as a Substitute for Bank Loans," in Edward I. Altman (ed.) The High-Yield Debt Market: Investment Performance and Economic Impact (Homewood, IL: Dow Jones-Irwin, 1990), p. 211.
Within these sets of arrangements, two broad forms of investment can be iden­tified: the synchronic and the diachronic. Saussure distinguishes the synchronic from the diachronic in his study of language. ™ The synchronic refers to the logic of a lan­guage, or the relations of coexistence among its elements. The diachrony of language seeks the origins and processes of language development.
These ideas were subsequently applied to social analysis by Sorel and, later, Piaget. Sorel linked the prominence of the synchronic study of all things with the maximizing proclivities of the newly emerging middle classes of his time/7 Syn­chronic thought, Sorel argued, is best understood as a technology of accumulation.38
36.   Ferdinand de Saussure, Course in General Linguistics (La Salle, 111.: Open Court, 1983).
37.    Georges Sorel, Reflections on Violence, trans. T. E. Ilulme and J. Roth (New York: Collier, 1961), 141.
38.     Piaget makes the case for understanding both the synchronic and the diachronic. But he argues that one does not necessarily follow the other, though the two are interconnected. (Jean Piaget, Sociological Studies [London: Routledge, 1995], 50).

Unconscious Power 59

The synchronic form is characteristically concerned with the short term and with the profits that can be accumulated in financial markets. The diachronic invest­ment form links financial activity directly to investment in productive assets that improve the social stock of material capabilities. In broad terms, the United States, Britain, and other English-speaking countries fall into the synchronic category. Most European and emerging market countries are best characterized in diachronic terms. Rating agencies promote the tendency toward convergence around syn­chronic investment norms and, therefore, to a consolidation of the investment prac­tices Zysman identifies.39
Zysman underestimates the degree to which the capital market is actually organ­ized. The ascendant financial type can best be described as the institutionalized cap­ital market form, in which rating agencies and related institutions construct an analytical basis for market transactions. These institutions promulgate synchronic norms. Market interactions that take place via the institutionalized capital market form typically reflect synchronic norms and thus are relevant in adapting policy frameworks in corporations, municipalities, and sovereign governments. Centraliza­tion of investment judgments is characteristic of institutionalized capital markets, even if a comparison of bank lending and capital markets at first suggests a less cen­tralized system than a bank-dominated one. With this substantive centralization, operating assumptions are premised on synchronic norms.
Knowledge is a key clement in the political economy of rating. Rating agencies pro­duce knowledge that is socially and politically partial, and then objectify this knowl­edge, making it authoritative. In turn, rating knowledge takes on a particular, instrumental form consequential for all.
People think of knowledge as separate from social relationships, as neutral and abstract. But knowledge—its creation and the particular forms it assumes in differ­ent times and places—is a product of conflicts between social interests.40 Researeh on epistemic communities, discussed in chapter 1, has highlighted the extent to which the intellectual work these communities undertake, such as problem identifi­cation and policy advice, represent efforts at social control over knowledge.41
39.     On convergence (and the resilience of national capitalist models), see Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore, eds., National Diversity and Global Capitalism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996).
40.    See the discussion of science as an ideology in Jorge Larrain, The Concept of Ideology (Athens: University of Georgia Press, 1979), 14.
41.     Peter A I. Haas, "Epistemic Communities and International Policy Coordination," Interna­tional Organization 46, no. 1 (Winter 1992): 2. The political significance of this activity is clarified by Diane Stone, Capturing the Political Imagination: Think Tanks and the Policy Process (London: Frank Cass, 1996).

60 The New Masters, of Capital

Strange is also concerned with knowledge, how it is made and who benefits from it. She argues that a "knowledge structure" exists at the heart of the world economy, alongside other major structures associated with finance, production, and security.42 Her view implies that rating knowledge becomes significant as knowledge, not so much because of its quality or informational value—but because it addresses issues that powerful social interests consider important.
Valuable knowledge—powerful knowledge—is so because it is socially validated. Knowledge is not inherently valuable or powerful but only when it is instrumental to, say, a specific phase of capitalist development. That is why knowledge of the Internet was valuable to young IT graduates in the mid-1990s but after the "dot.com" crash of the late 1990s, much less so. The knowledge itself did not change. I low that knowledge fitted into capitalism did—dramatically.
Instrumental Knowledge
Rating agencies fit into a specific capitalist knowledge structure. Market participants view rating agencies as endogenous (rather than exogenous) to global finance.41 Rat­ing agencies are therefore seen by market participants as legitimate rather than imposed entities. In chapter one, we referred to this specific understanding of the nature and role of the agencies as embedded knowledge networks, the bigger set of mechanisms to which the rating agencies belong. How rating agencies construct, reinforce, and reconstruct this collective view of rating agencies as embedded knowl­edge networks is a crucial feature of global finance. The risk is that embedded knowl­edge networks lose their embedded identity as they move into new territories. As we will see, this is a constraint on the expansion of the major U.S. agencies into emerg­ing markets (as it was for them in Europe).
The specific form of knowledge promoted by rating agencies is instrumental in character, focused on immediate gain rather than growth based on sustainable social reproduction. The instrumental form of knowledge is linked to a synchronic under­standing of the world.
What are the characteristic elements of the synchronic, instrumental form of knowledge? There are two central principles. The first principle is the universaliza- tion of self-regulating markets and the exoticization of other modes of social inter­action. Although never realized in the concrete, the notion of a self-regulating market, a market free from state interference and redistributive costs, has become a
42.   Susan Strange, States and Markets 2nd ed. (London: Pinter, 1994), 30.
43.     Granovettcr, writing against the assumptions of the New Institutional Economics, empha­sized endogeneity. He suggested that economic action is "embedded in ongoing networks of per­sonal relations rather than carried out by atomized actors." In these circumstances, economic institutions (like all institutions) do not develop spontaneously but are constructed (Mark Gra­novettcr, "Economic Institutions as Social Construction: A Framework for Analysis," Acta Socio- togica 35 [1992]: 3-11,4).

Unconscious Power 61

central organizing focus in Western societies since the 1970s. Other forms of social organization are, it seems, increasingly to be judged against this norm. The resur­gence of the self-regulating market norm makes any sense of intentional community action open to question not on its merits but, more important, in principle.
The second principle of synchronic, instrumental knowledge is its tendency to identify time and space merely as obstacles, of no value, and therefore as problems to be overcome. Synchronic, instrumental knowledge is centrally concerned with faster turnover, just-in-time practices, the application of financial analysis tools such as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), and the maximization of efficiency gains. However, the evaluation of investment opportunities using techniques like CAPM or discounted cash flow (DCF) analysis, to the exclusion of other types of informa­tion and forms of judgment, perhaps undervalues "less quantifiable strategic bene­fits," such as the acquisition of market share.44
Knowledge is a key dimension of the rating world. Rating knowledge is partial and political. Some knowledge is validated and considered a source of influence yet is represented as objective. The form of knowledge rating agencies use is synchronic and instrumental. The utilization of this knowledge form, when linked to the gate­keeping role of the agencies, is consequential. Those seeking the acclamation of the agencies have strong incentives to adopt the synchronic instrumental knowledge form, with attendant consequences.
Most Americans think that the large, well-known credit rating organi­zations like Moody's and Standard & Poor's are purely private enter­prises: they are unaware of the fact that these organizations are, in fact, more properly viewed as quasi-governmental entities.
Jonathan R. Macky, U.S. Senate, Mareh 20, 2002
It is one thing to claim that rating agencies are consequential at some times and in some places. It is another to claim that they are political in nature. How are ratings politically important? Macey's argument about the agencies' quasi-governmental status is significant here. But politics also influence the rating process.
Rating is not the technical activity it is thought popularly to be. Instead, it is highly indeterminate, qualitative, and judgment laden. Rating is, first and foremost, about creating an interpretation of the world and about the routine production of practical judgments based on that interpretation. This interpretation is made within the terms of the socialization and interests of rating agency officials, who are part of a wider financial and analytical community. The authoritative rather than persuasive
44. Michael T.Jacobs, Short-Term America (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1991), 179.
62 The New Masters, of Capital
nature of bond rating conceals the qualitative processes of rating determination. Those processes, if widely known, would perhaps lead to a more skeptical use of rat­ing information by investors.
Rating agencies do not limit their analysis to quantitative debt or income data, as people typically assume. Their view of management structure, policy, and the wider context of the issuer—all of which are contestable issues—make the credit rating process inherently a nondeductive matter. This judgment process implies gatekeep­ing, and gatekeeping is—even when not intended explicitly—manifestly political. Moreover, as discussed earlier, the bond rating agencies tend to promote specific frameworks of investment practices, knowledge forms, and governance systems. In any other context, these views would be readily recognizable as instances of politi­cal ideology.4"1
This book does not claim that rating agencies are biased or conspiratorial in their operations, although this may be the case at times. The argument is that the logic of rating is linked to a particular form of social organization and set of interests. It does not represent a universally beneficial system, as might be otherwise assumed. Raters try to avoid any hint of partiality and seek to appear as scientific as they can. Nor, for the most part, are rating officials cynical about this. As one senior rating official said, the "true believers" in the rating agencies think they really are neutral and objective. The "pragmatists," the informant observed, see what they are doing much more in terms of judgment and are skeptical about the potential for a truly objective or scientific view.46 Certainly, raters are no more cynical than other groups who have sought to professionalize themselves and thereby acquire social standing and a big­ger share of resources.47
Even if the work of rating agencies involved no interpretation or judgment, it would still not be "objective" in a wider sense. The rating mode of thought is premised on the assumptions of the given social and economic order. The signifi­cance of the cognitive frame used in credit rating becomes clearer in the context of international capital mobility. Credit rating serves as a vetting and surveillance system for capital mobility, allowing mobility to occur "securely" across geo­graphic and cultural space. The agencies can be thought of as representing the interests of international or external capital to sovereign countries and corpora­tions seeking capital. Andrews has argued that international capital mobility is a structure, which states encounter and must respond to, as they do the international
45.     Ideology is used not in the sense of bias, untruth, or distorted ideas. The meaning adopted here follows Larrain, who suggests interests mobilize different ways of thinking. There is 110 uni­versal or pan-social interest or knowledge. (Larrain, 1979).
46.   Senior rating official, confidential source, New York Citv, April 2002.
47.     On professionalization (and its links with knowledge), see Andrew Abbott, The System of Professions: An Essay on the Division of Expert Labor (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988); and Harold Perkin, The Third Revolution: Professional Elites in the Modern World (New York: Rout­ledge, 1996).

Unconscious Power 63

system of states.48 In this structure, rating agencies serve an important policing role enforcing the needs of the structure and clarifying its signals to states, corpora­tions, and municipalities.
There is a second sense in which we need to take rating agencies seriously in polit­ical terms, premised on this first argument about the partiality of rating judgments. That is, the judgments raters make have important distributional consequences for society. The agencies1 output influences the global distribution of money, jobs, and economic opportunity. Hence, they are highly consequential actors in the global economy. What they say and do is too important for our collective global welfare to be considered nonpolitical. The "who gets what, when, how" questions of distribu­tion are the sort of political questions that cannot be separated from a broader con­sideration of bond rating.49 An insistence that rating agencies are not political is really an assertion that the market should be above social intervention. The partial­ity of such an affirmation needs little emphasis.
If rating agencies are political, do they also exercise power or something like power in their work? Rating agencies do, at times, exercise power in the common- sense definition of the term: A gets B to do what B would not otherwise do.50 A less- understood feature of this power is the ability to define a situation as a crisis of creditworthiness, when the facts are really a matter of interpretation.1' The rela­tional form of power is complemented by a second, more significant form of power, which is structural. This exists when the perceived relational power of the agencies is anticipated by others who act in advance of the agencies1 explicit judgments, to avoid any actual exercise of power. The idea of structural power docs not capture the full extent of rating agency influence, however.
An altogether more hidden form of social control than either relational or struc­tural power resides in the agencies1 authority. The concept of authority is often used in a narrow, legal context to describe the legitimate, lawful status of an entity. That is not the usage here.
A key distinction in the concept of authority is between the epistemic authority of technical experts, scholars, and professionals, who are "an authority," and exec­utive authority, of political leaders, military officers, and police forces, who are "in authority."52 What both have in common characterizes the auctoritas of Roman law,
48.    David M. Andrews, "Capital Mobility and State Autonomy: Toward a Structural Theory of International Monetary Relations," International Studies Quarterly 38, no. 2 (June 1994): 193-218.
49.  Harold D. Lasswell, Politics: Who Gets What, When, How (Cleveland: World Publishing, 1958).
50.     On power, see Steven Lukes, Power: A Radical View (London: Macmillan, 1974); John Scott, Power (Cambridge: Polity, 2001); and Sallie Westwood, Power and the Social (New York: Routledge, 2002).
51.     On this process of crisis definition, see Davita Silfen Glasberg, The Power of Collective Purse Strings: The Effect of Bank Hegemony on Corporations and the State (Berkeley: University of Cali­fornia Press, 1989), 19.
52.    Bruce Lincoln, Authority: Construction and Corrosion (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1994), 3-4.

64 The New Masters, of Capital

namely, they produce "consequential speech'1 that quells doubts, winning the trust of audiences. Lincoln argues that the consequentiality of authoritative speech actu­ally has little to do with the form or content of what is said. There is a hierarehy that allows some speakers to command not just audience attention but also their confi­dence, respect, and trust.
I .incoin concludes that historical circumstances are crucial to identifying the exis­tence of authority. Authority is best understood as an effect of these circumstances, rather than as an entity or a characteristic of an actor or institution. Its existence is therefore not functional, easily understood through a rationalist lens, but always con­tingent on time, place, and circumstance. Capacities for producing these effects are central to understanding authority, as are understandings of who—what actors— have the capacity for producing the effect at specific times in particular places.
The notion of authority, or epistemic authority, may suggest to some a system of relations in which no opposition is possible, in which the rating agencies control the views and actions of all who need their services. This is not the intention in using the concept. The authority of rating agencies is ambiguous and shifting, like other norms. In writing about the Italian-American community of East Harlem, Orsi dis­cussed the role of the southern Italian notion of rispetto. Orsi suggested rispetto was "above all ... a posture of obedience to authority.Respect and fear were bound up together in the notion. But rispetto was a public posture, which often concealed disagreement. This private hostility Scott has called the "hidden transcript."^ The important thing is that disagreement was rarely aired publicly, and the mask of rispetto was maintained. Rispetto is a good approximation of the fear-respect rela­tions that exist between rating agencies and those dependent on their judgments.
Authority is not persuasion. The major rating agencies do not seek to persuade others to agree with their views. Indeed, as Lincoln suggests, "The exercise of authority need not involve argumentation and may rest on the naked assertion that the identity of the speaker warrants acceptance of the speech.Persuasive efforts (and coercion, too) reveal a lack of authority. As Hannah Arendt observed, author­ity can be defined in contrast to both coercion and persuasion.5' Persuasion and coercion are implicit within authority but are actualized only when authority itself is in jeopardy. Their explicit actualization gives a signal that, at least temporarily, authority is negated.58
53.   Ibid., 10.
54.    Robert Anthony Orsi, The Madonna of115th Street: Faith and Community in Italian Harlem, 1880-1950 (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1985), 93.
55.   Scott, 1990, xii.
56.   Lincoln, 1994, 5.
57.     Arendt cited in David Miller, "Authority," in Miller, ed., The Blackwell Encyclopaedia of Political Thought (Oxford: Blackwell, 1991), 29. Arendt sets out her ideas about authority in Between Past and Future: Six Exercises in Political Thought (London: Faber and Faber, 1954).
58.   Lincoln, 1994, 6.

Unconscious Power 65

Epistemic authority is not impermeable. The authority of rating agencies (or at least its scope) has expanded with the growth of capital markets and the decline of banks as major allocators of resources. Rating agencies have moved from a more per­suasive role into that of epistemic authority, or embedded knowledge network. Per­suasion implies a range of levels of respect. Epistemic authority is bivariate: authority either exists or is absent. By its very nature, it is hard to budge once generated, because market participants tend to discount the "mistakes" or epistemic failures of the agen­cies, given their identity as authorities. Of course, these resources could be over­whelmed by a persistent record of perceived failure or by a change in the relationship between raters and those who use ratings—a change in the structure of capitalism.
Rating agencies, especially Moody's and Standard & Poor's, worked hard to cre­ate a reputation for impartiality. In situations where people surrender their powers of judgment to an institution or to a group, the surrender may be quite fragile, as in the case of a fad or fashion. '19 Or, as the notion of rispetto suggests, it may be largely a public posture. The circumstances, including the longevity of the rating agencies, make their particular authoritative niche more resilient than that of most other non- state institutions. Their position within the capital markets gives them considerable epistemic resources. Moreover, even if individuals do become skeptical about rating agencies, as often happens, they cannot necessarily assume others in the markets have, too. This risk gives skeptical individuals incentives to act based on the assump­tion that others also use the rating agencies as benchmarks, unless they know this definitely not to be the case.
What is missing in Lincoln's argument about authority is an understanding of the criteria that determine when the elements he identifies as the "right ones" actu­ally become right. What generates authority is, as he suggests, a reflection of cir­cumstances encountered and is therefore highly individuated. But the basic relationship between those with authority and those who acknowledge authority can be discerned. This relationship centers on the social efficacy of the ideas those claim­ing authority hold. In terms of foreign policy, it has been suggested, ideas "provide road maps that increase actors' clarity about goals or ends-means relationships."60 This road map analogy establishes a concrete mechanism controlling the relation­ship between the authoritative and the nonauthoritative, which might otherwise seem nebulous.
Creditworthiness is a road map providing a mechanism for the relation between authority and nonauthority. Creditworthiness is both a causal belief—being credit­worthy means that debt issuers are likely to repay their debts—and a principled
59.     Sushil Bikchandani, David Hirshleifer, and Ivo Welch, "A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Cus­tom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades," Journal of Political Economy 100, no. 5 (1992): 1016.
60.     Judith Goldstein and Robert O. Keohane, "Ideas and Foreign Policy: An Analytical Frame­work," in Goldstein and Keohane, eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1993), 3.

66 The New Masters, of Capital

belief, in that placing a priority on repaying debt is morally right and obligatory. As a belief, creditworthiness becomes embedded in rules and norms, that is, institu­tionalized, acting like other beliefs in the manner of "invisible switchmen" to "con­strain public policy" by "turning action onto certain tracks," thus obscuring other tracks from view.61 Katzenstein suggests that institutionalized norms like creditwor­thiness do not merely influence behavior by prescribing ends but also indirectly organize action.62 How creditworthiness came to be institutionalized like this is a fascinating question, requiring what Goldstein and Keohane call an "arehaeology of ideas."63 In any case, the mechanism is not monolithic. As Katzenstein warns, norms remain contested and contingent.
In an insightful analysis of financial auditing, Michael Power makes an argument similar to Goldstein and Keohane's about semantic or programmatic effects.64 The subject cannot be reduced merely to the technocratic and the functional, he argues. Auditing is "implicated in the framing of organizational life," contributing a style of evaluation or self-monitoring that underpins how organizations work. Like rat­ing, auditing involves a "certain obscurity in the professional craft," which con­tributes to its monopoly privilege. Practitioners defend this obscurity against codification, to preserve their scope for judgment.
Unlike intellectuals, auditors—and raters, too—do not invite public dialog, debate, or democratic deliberation. Audit reports, like ratings, are labels. By virtue of a rhetoric of "neutrality, objectivity, dispassion, expertise," reports and ratings do not communicate passively but tell or as Power says, "give off" an understanding or view premised on trust in experts—authorities. But this understanding is not meant for public deliberation. I.ike an auditor, a rater has emerged "not just as one who exercises expert judgement but also as one who is in the role of judge."65
Two more specific claims about governance and rating agencies are addressed in this discussion: first, nonstate forms of governance increasingly matter in the con­temporary world, and second, the forms of governance rating agencies "encourage" contribute to patterns of public and private policymaking.
As we have seen, bond rating agencies are unusual entities to consider politically. They are privately owned and not directly involved in electoral politics. The analy­sis is different from that for legislatures, regulatory agencies, or political parties, even though the agencies are also subject to constraints relating to their organiza­tional character. No doubt, many of the conceptual tools applied to public bureau­cracies could be used to establish a better understanding of them, too (if the same
61.   Ibid., 12.
62.    Peter J. Katzenstein, "Coping with Terrorism: Norms and Internal Security in Germany and Japan," in Goldstein and Keohane, eds., 1993, 267.
63.   Ibid., 21.
64.    Michael Power, The Au/Ht Society: Rituals of Verification (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1997). Peter Katzenstein and Dieter Kerwer separately suggested Power's book to me.
65.   Ibid., 8,74, 127,40.

Unconscious Power 67

sort of internal data was available). However, a critical first evaluation of bond rat­ing agencies must get at the governance outputs they produce. What is it about the type of institution rating agencies represent that is different from those political sci­entists more usually analyze?
Governance focuses on the processes associated with the exercise of control rather than on administrative mechanisms considered in abstraction/'6 In the ortho­dox view, transactions are understood to occur exclusively in the realm of the mar­ket, and legal authority is a feature of governments. However, this orthodoxy is less persuasive in the contemporary world. A more effective conception acknowledges that nonstate forms of governance have always been important but that financial globalization has made these institutions and networks more central to capitalism. Their interactions with each other and with states are essential to an understanding of contemporary governance.
Ferguson and Mansbach contend that states are less important as a result of "his­torical sea changes," which have displaced one form of political organization from "pride of place" in our world.67 Limitation of authority to the legally binding actions of governments is no longer persuasive. Instead, they suggest the idea of "effective governance"is more useful today.68
Miller and Rose endorse this concern.69 They add that "technologies of thought," such as writing, numbering, compiling, and computing, render a realm knovvable, calculable, and thus governable. This notion is clearly applicable to the world of rating. "Procedures of inscription" make objects like the economy and the firm amenable to intervention and regulation. Such "humble and mundane mecha­nisms," combined with interventionary policy goals (what Miller and Rose call "programs of government"), have over time dissolved the distinction between state and civil society. What has been most vital are the ways in which these indirect mech­anisms of rule have enabled "government at a distance " to be maintained. This form of domination involves "intellectual mastery," based on the possession of critical information, by those at the center over persons and events distant from them.70The objective of rule at a distance is to create a framework in which social forces are self- regulating within the norms of the system.
Rating agencies have an impact on the governance undertaken by other institu­tions. Financial globalization has created an unprecedented degree of volatility in
66.   James N. Rosenau, "Governance in the Twenty-First Century," Global Governance 1, no. 1 (1995): 13.
67.     Yale H. Ferguson and Richard W. Mansbach, "Between Celebration and Despair: Construc­tive Suggestions for Future International Theory," InternationaI Studies Quarterly 35, no. 4 (December 1991): 371.
68.  Ibid., 376.
69.     Peter Miller and Nikolas Rose, "Governing Economic Life," Economy and Society 19, no. 1 (February 1990): 2, and "Political Power beyond the State: Problematics of Government," British Journal of Sociology 43, no. 2 (June 1992): 173-205.
70.   Ibid., 1990, 5, 8, 9.

68 The New Masters, of Capital

socioeconomic circumstances. One response to this has been initiatives to separate central bank monetary policy from legislative intervention and to establish "fiscal responsibility acts," as in the case of New Zealand, which set out principles for "pru­dent" fiscal policy.7' Another response has been a shift in emphasis between what have come to be called "fire alarm" and "police patrol"-type surveillance forms.72 The fire alarm metaphor refers to a problem-focused, episodic approach to gover­nance. Municipal fire departments give problems like fires attention only when they have been identified and called in by nonspecialists. A framework is established— fires are reported by those who see them—that requires only occasional enforce­ment. Inspections are infrequent (perhaps annually), and the emphasis is on self-regulation in self-interest. In the case of police patrols, a much more aggressive process of looking for law-breaking is characteristic. The idea is that many problems never mature into crises because of surveillance and early intervention.
Although fire alarm approaches may be cheaper in cost-benefit terms, police patrol surveillance is attractive when the immediate costs of disgovernance are very high and losses are "lumpy"—what Hubert calls low-probability, high-consequence risk. An example of the latter is when a major bond issuer unexpectedly defaults and a crisis of confidence arises in financial markets as a whole.'3
Public institutions seem to be increasingly moving from the police patrol to the fire alarm approach, under fiscal and competitive deregulation pressures from fi­nancial globalization. Paradoxically, a tightening of governance is developing in the private realm, as institutions with the capacity for governance seek to compensate for the risks and opportunities change creates. Rating agencies are part of this tightening.
Rating agencies adjust the "ground rules" inside international capital markets and thereby shape the organization and behavior of institutions seeking funds. This anticipation effect is reflected in capital market participants' understandings of the agencies' expectat ions. In turn, from this point of origin, business and policy initia­tives are developed. This coordination, or government-at-a-distance effect, narrows the expectations of creditors and debtors to a shared set of norms derived from the prevailing orthodoxy about corporate governance and public policy structures. Thus, the agencies do not just constrain the broad capital markets, but they actually
71.   "The Great Escape?" Economist, April 1, 1995, 60.
72.     Mathew D. McCubbins and Thomas Schwartz, "Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms," in McCubbins and Sullivan, eds., Congress: Structure and Pol­icy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), 427.
73.     Don Hubert, "Popular Responses to Global Insecurity: Public Encounters with Low- Probability High-Consequence Risk," paper presented to the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Chicago, February 1995; also see Virginia Haufler, "Learning to Cope: Inter­national Risk Management in History," paper presented to the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, Chicago, February 1995; Ulrich Beck, Risk Society: Towards a New Moder­nity, trans. Mark Ritter (Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage, 1992); and Anthony Giddens, Modernity and Self-Identity: Self and Society in the Late Modern Age (Cambridge, UK: Polity, 1991).
Unconscious Power 69
exert significant pressures on market participants, contributing to their internal con­stitution or identity as market agents.
Mental Framework of Rating Orthodoxy
The purpose of a mental framework of rating orthodoxy, presented in table 5, is to clarify the fundamental assumptions underlying rating, set out here in ideal-typical form. Fundamental principles central to the agencies—orthodox, synchronic prin­ciples—are contrasted with a heterodox, diachronic set. Like the first set, the sec­ond is not exhaustive but merely indicates the diversity of conceivable thinking.
The framework is a codified version of the "rating myth." Myth, as Meyer and Rowan and Power have noted, is a key to understanding why institutions are organ­ized as they are and operate as they do. The components of the rating myth within the mental framework of rating orthodoxy should be seen as a set of norms for the agencies' work.

Conclusions

What is rating? In a narrow sense, rating is simply a technical support system for the new global capital markets. In a broader view, bond rating is much more than a tech­nical support system. It is the arehetype of a new form of institutional coordination developing in conditions of financial globalization. Based in markets rather than for­mal governmental structures, bond rating is at odds with the consensus that under­pinned the post-World War II political economy of embedded liberalism. That postwar world order was built on a compromise between producer and consumer, owner and worker, investor and employee. 'The work of bond rating agencies, as the mental framework of rating orthodoxy suggests, implicitly attacks these compro­mises and promotes the interests of investors, as interpreted and constructed by the rating agencies. °
Rating agencies should be understood therefore as a crucial nerve center in the world order, as a nexus of neoliberal control.76 Like an operating system in a personal
74.     John Gerrard Ruggie, "Embedded Liberalism and the Postwar Economic Regimes," in Ruggie, Constructing the World Polity: Essays on International Institutionalization (New York: Rout- ledge, 1998); also see Mark Rupert, Producing Hegemony: The Politics of Mass Production and Amer­ican Global Power (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1995); and Robert W. C.ox, Production, Power, and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History (New York: Columbia University Press, 1987).
75.    On the interests of investors, see Adam Harmes, "Institutional Investors and the Reproduc­tion of Neoliberalism," Review of International Political Economy 5, no. 1 (Spring 1998): 92-121.
76.    Kees van der Pijl, Transnational Classes and International Relations (New York: Routledge, 1998), 5.

70 The New Masters, of Capital

Table 5. The mental framework of rating orthodoxy
Synchronic-rationalist principles (orthodoxy)
Diachronic-constructivist principles (heterodoxy)
Investment • Ratings are the result of rational professional processes.
• Emphasis on short-terms returns and the specification of liabilities. Valuation of profit-making as means of repayment. May take place in production or financial markets.
Knowledge • Knowledge is objective, cross- cultural and instrumental. Markets are natural and sponta­neous, not social phenomena. Technical expertise is essential to creation of knowledge. All knowl­edge producers are equal and are only as good as their last output. Competition between sources of knowledge negates any perverse social dynamic to falsely accord eminence to knowledge producers.
Governance • Rating is not political.
Rating challenges historically- derived norms and practices assumed to inhibit efficient resource allocation. Emphasis on self-regulatory "police patrol"-type systems. Priva­tization may result. This is seen as politically neutral.
Ratings are the result of judgments.
Emphasis on sustainable growth in environment of collective absorption of risk. Valuation of profit-making and taxation as means of repayment, based on investment in productive capabilities and social infrastructure.
Social dynamics are central to the creation, content and eminence granted to different knowledges. Markets are social phenomena Reputation, based on experience, underpins epistemic authority (e.g. embedded knowledge net­works). All knowledge producers are not equal—the intersubjective identity of a knowledge producer as an epistemic authority gives authority to this knowledge pro­ducer's subsequent output(good or bad).
Rating is political. Emphasis on valid role of multiple stakeholders and the social distri­bution of costs and benefits. Influence of rating establishes potential for government-at-a- distance.
computer, rating agencies, although usually unseen, monitor global life at the high­est levels, with important social and political effects. In conditions of financial glob­alization, rating agencies serve as intelligence-gathering, data-analyzing mechanisms.
The mid-range arguments made in chapter 1 were developed here conceptually and empirically. The ideas presented here, as captured by the rating orthodoxy framework, provide the analytical core for the following substantive chapters. Rat­ing incorporates both quantitative and qualitative variables. It is crucial to acknowl­edge this, for much of the commentary in the financial media passes over the inherent indeterminancy of bond rating. What follows from this observation that ratings are judgments is that rating is more contestable than it at first appears.

Unconscious Power 71

Particular solutions to problems, such as how to fund the construction and mainte­nance of a bridge, can have vet }' different answers. Some answers, such as funding from general revenue, bias the distribution of resources toward certain groups (such as drivers) and away from others (e.g., taxpayers). Other solutions, such as the impo­sition of tolls, target all who drive over a bridge but negatively affect low-income people, whose mobility is reduced accordingly. These distributional effects are key political consequences of rating, but they rarely receive acknowledgment.
What are some consequences of this new form of power? Rating agencies and the rating process provide a means for transmitting policy and managerial orthodoxy to widely scattered governments and corporations. In this sense, the agencies are nom­inally private makers of a global public policy. They are agents of convergence who, along with other institutions, try to enforce "best practice" or "transparency" around the globe. The rating agencies are promoters of an American-derived, syn­chronic mental framework. The most significant effect of rating agencies is not, therefore, their view of budget deficits or some other specific policy but their influ­ence on how issuers assess problems in general. This adjustment of mental schemata is the most consequential impact of their work.

vedio transcript

 00:13 vì có một số nguyên vật liệu cần đăng ký mua, vậy nên chúng ta sẽ bắt đầu nói về việc mua mặt hàng này trước. 00:23 bộ phận thu mua...